Why Do some Member States Offer so much Fiscal Aid?

Why Do some Member States Offer so much Fiscal Aid? - StateaidHub blogpost11 Lexxion 2019 Tax Commission EU judgement scaled

Member States differ significantly in their propensity to grant fiscal aid.

 

Introduction

Interest in fiscal aid has been rekindled recently by two unrelated events. First, the Commission opened a number of investigations on the alleged special tax treatment accorded to multinational companies such as Apple and Starbucks. These investigations are believed to be almost completed and the Commission is expected to issue its decisions soon. Second, the General Court of the EU delivered a surprising judgment in a case concerning a certain tax deduction obtained by Spanish companies whenever they acquired companies abroad.[1] Although it was an exemption from the normal tax, and exemptions are almost always found to constitute State aid, the General Court concluded that it could be a general measure. The Court thought that the Commission failed to prove that the exemption was limited only to some companies.

When one asks why Member State resort to fiscal aid, the typical explanations fall into three types of answers: i) that Member States attempt to design tax measures that fall outside the scope of Article 107(1), which is the holy grail of policies for the support of business; or ii) that Member States attempt to favour certain undertakings surreptitiously through opaque tax deals; or iii) that Member States do not have enough budgetary resources to support grant-based measures.

The first step towards understanding the motives of Member States is to understand what in fact they do. An analysis of the data in DG Competition’s State aid Scoreboard reveals surprising differences across Member States.

The next section presents these data. The last section constructs a numerical example to determine whether a country should be providing grant aid or fiscal aid.

Startling differences among Member States

According to the State aid Scoreboard published annually by DG Competition, the Member States of the European Union provide aid primarily in the following forms: grants, tax exemptions or tax deferrals, low-interest loans, guarantees, equity injections and use of state assets or services at prices below market level. The two main forms are grants [accounting for about 55% of total aid] and fiscal aid [about 35%]. Because together they make up slightly more than 90% of all aid, Table 1 below does not include other forms of aid. Table 1 covers the ten-year period from 2004 to 2013, which is the latest year for which statistics are available. This period is chosen because 2004 was the year of the largest of the three recent enlargements of the EU.

With respect to grants, not surprisingly, the largest Member States provide more aid than the rest. Yet, even among the four largest Member States, there are significant differences. Germany of course is in the lead, given that it has the largest economy in Europe. The economies of France, Italy and the UK are roughly the same size. But France grants almost twice as much as Italy and Italy grants almost twice as much as the UK. There are also surprising differences among smaller countries. For example, Denmark accounts for 5% of all grants which puts it at the same level as Poland whose economy is 60% larger. [In bold are Member States with shares exceeding 5%.]


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

The column of grants can serve as a benchmark to appreciate the variations among Member States with respect to fiscal aid. Fiscal aid is broken down in tax exemptions and tax deferrals, as presented by DG Competition in its Scoreboard. When it comes to tax exemptions, the dominance of Germany is even more pronounced. Germany and France alone account for more than 50% of all aid in the form of tax exemptions in the decade 2004-13. There is also the appearance of Sweden and the UK in the top four. Sweden which provides a mere 1% of grant aid, when it comes to tax exemptions it jumps to third place with a tenfold increase.

The last column on tax deferrals also contains a few surprises. The top four countries are now Italy, the Netherlands, Romania and the UK. Italy and the Netherlands together have a share that exceeds 65% of the EU total. The presence of Romania in the top four is also perplexing.

Table 1: State aid, 2004-13: Non-crisis grants and fiscal aid

Grants

2004-13 [million EUR]

% of total EU grants Tax exemptions

2004-13 [million EUR]

Tax deferrals

2004-13 [million EUR]

EU28 418062.5 100 258463.2 6891.6
Belgium 10249.3 2 4744.4 0
Bulgaria 602.5 0 446.2 3.8
Czech Republic 8611.6 2 2585.9 0
Denmark 19329.3 5 2018.9 0
Germany 83672.8 20 69413.2

[27%]

 

0
Estonia 194.6 0 280.2 0
Ireland 6674.1 2 4267.1 12.7
Greece 8951.6 2 2474.1 0
Spain 32255.8 8 11418.7 56.5
France 78865.6 19
65828.0
[25%]
11.2
Croatia 145.4 0 17.4 0
Italy 44264.5 11 6025.8
2616.0
[38%]
Cyprus 1134.0 0 255.0 0
Latvia 2262.6 1 237.7 0.2
Lithuania 902.4 0 851.4 3.9
Luxembourg 1086.2 0 0 0
Hungary 8683.4 2 5908.6 0
Malta 452.0 0 867.2 0
Netherlands 14287.8 3 4542.9 1909.8 [28%]
Austria 14015.1 3 1914.8 0
Poland 22196.4 5 5465.0 19.9
Portugal 2539.5 1 12844.8

[5%]

 

155.4
Romania 5993.7 1 2277.3 1505.8

[22%]

 

Slovenia 2437.0 1 332.3 0
Slovakia 1130.1 0 1847.9 0
Finland 16436.0 4 4380.8 0
Sweden 5329.2 1 28685.5

[11%]

 

0
United Kingdom 25360.7 6 18531.7

[7%]

596.2

[9%]

Source: European Commission, DG Competition, State Aid Scoreboard. Own calculations.

Casual perusal of the statistics published by DG Competition suggests that there is no single explanation that fits all Member States. Fiscal aid is provided by both rich and poor Member States. Moreover, why do some countries seem to be enamoured with fiscal aid? Why does Germany provide significantly more fiscal aid than grant aid? Why do Italy, the Netherlands, Romania and the UK appear to monopolise tax deferrals? If grants are the popular or preferred form of aid, why are Portugal and Sweden the only two Member States that provide more fiscal aid than grants and why do they give six times more fiscal aid than grants? These are important questions which, however, cannot be answered on the basis of data published by DG Competition.

What are the consequences of providing fiscal aid?

First it is necessary to understand how fiscal aid is provided. All aid, in any form, must be approved before the eligible project or activity starts. But normally, the money is actually given to the eligible undertaking at a later stage. Unlike a grant which, as a matter of standard practice, is normally transferred to an undertaking when the eligible project or activity is completed, fiscal aid is made available not just on completion of a project or activity but when the undertaking closes its accounts at the end of the financial year. The provision of fiscal aid requires assessment and decisions by two different authorities: the granting authority and the tax authority. The granting authority first assesses whether the proposed project or activity is eligible for aid. Then it furnishes the aid beneficiary with confirmation that it can receive at the end of the fiscal year an amount of aid in the form of exemption or reduction from a tax which is normally the corporate tax. That is, fiscal aid is in reality a tax credit that can be used at a point in the future. When the beneficiary closes its accounts, after completion of the eligible project, and the tax authority calculates its taxable income, if the beneficiary makes profit, the amount of tax credit is subtracted from its tax liability. A simple example can illuminate this process.

Assume that a company proposes to carry out a project that requires up-front investment of 100. The operating cost of the project over its lifetime is 50. That is, its total cost is 150. The projected revenue is 130. This means that the project faces a deficit [or funding gap] of 20. No rational investor would invest in a loss-making project. This means that aid is necessary and has an incentive effect. Also assume that the project is proposed to be carried out in a region that is eligible for investment aid at a rate of 30%. In this case, the amount of aid is 30. In addition, assume that the company is liable for corporate tax or profit tax at a rate of 25%.

Why Do some Member States Offer so much Fiscal Aid? - Banner Transport Hub%20Kopie

The company receives 30 when it invests 100. Its operating costs over the life of the project [assume that all numbers are discounted to year 1] are 150 [= 100 + 50], while its operating revenue is 130. Its profit is 10 [= 130 – (150 + 30)]. With the aid of 30 it receives, the project becomes profitable. With the aid, the gross profit of the company becomes 10 and it is liable for 2.5 of tax which means that its after-tax profit is 7.5. If the aid had been granted in a fiscal form, the company would have received a tax credit equal to 30 that it would set against its future tax liability.

This example helps us to note a paradox. We have already assumed that the project without aid is loss-making. We need to make this assumption in order to ensure that the aid has an incentive effect. But under these conditions, any tax credit or tax exemption or tax deferral is useless!! It becomes useful only if the company makes profit. Indeed, the example above demonstrates that a tax credit of 30 does not help the company because without the grant it makes a loss of 20. Therefore, we must infer that a tax credit/exemption/deferral is useful only if the company has other sources of income so that it can set its tax credit from the project against its tax liability that arises from other income.

The paradox is that if aid has an incentive effect [because the revenue from the project is insufficient to cover costs], a tax credit is useless. This means that, first, a tax credit is useful only if the beneficiary has other sources of income and, second, that fiscal aid necessarily links aided projects or activities with non-aided projects or activities. This linkage is not formal, but it is real in the sense that the beneficiary company must have other sources of income in the country that provides the tax credit.

What is the amount of extra (net) revenue, R, that when taxed at a rate of t = 25% yields a tax liability of 30 which corresponds to the amount of the grant? It can be calculated as follows. (R – 150)0.25 = 30. Therefore, R = 270.

If we plug these numbers in the numerical example above, we get as net profit = (revenue – costs) – (tax + tax credit) = (130 + 270 – 150) – ((130 + 270 – 150)0.25 + 30) = 217.5. By comparison, the net profit in the case of a grant aid is 210. Fiscal aid results in more profit for the company.

Impact on tax revenue

What is the effect on the finances of the granting Member State? In the first case [provision of only a grant], it spends 30 in terms of the grant and receives the following in terms of tax revenue: 2.5 [= 10 x 0.25] + 67.5 [= 270 x 0.25] = 70. This Member State experiences a net increase in state resources of 40 [= 70 – 30].

In the case of fiscal aid, it receives 62.5 of tax revenue [= 250 x 0.25] but gives away 30 of tax credit. Its net position is 32.5 [= 62.5 – 30]. It forgoes 7.5 of tax revenue which is exactly what the company gains in the case of fiscal aid [7.5 = 217.5 – 210]. Fiscal aid leads to less tax revenue.

When considering that one of the alleged motives of fiscal aid is the budget constraint [i.e. not enough budgetary resources], then it is indeed surprising why cash-strapped countries resort to fiscal aid which leaves the state budget with less money than in the case of outright grants.

Conclusions

There are significant differences among Member States in the use of fiscal aid. A handful of Member States account for the vast majority of the aid that is provided in fiscal form. Why this is so, it is not clear and should be the subject of future research.

More importantly, aid granted through fiscal instruments results in more profit for the beneficiary companies. Also, fiscal aid causes a net reduction in state resources in comparison to a situation where aid is provided in the form of grants. It is therefore, unclear why Member States provide fiscal aid instead of simple grants.

————————————————————————

[1] See T-399/11, Banco Santander v European Commission and T-219/10, Autogrill Espana v Commission.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

17. Dez 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Can a Tax (rather than a Tax Exemption) Confer a Selective Advantage? - StateAidHub blogpost52 Stateaid Lexxion TAX Water Spain European Commission

Can a Tax (rather than a Tax Exemption) Confer a Selective Advantage?

A tax that is levied at one level of government and does not apply to products and activities at a different level of government need not be selective. Introduction A tax exemption normally confers a selective advantage, unless it is justified by the logic of the tax. Counterintuitively, a tax itself can be selectively advantageous if its scope is too […]
03. Sep 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Presumed v Actual Compatibility of State aid with the Internal Market - StateAidHub blogpost36 GBER BMW

Presumed v Actual Compatibility of State aid with the Internal Market

State aid granted on the basis of the GBER may not be considered as authorised by the Commission. The task of Member States is to ensure that all of the requirements of the GBER are fulfilled. In particular, Member States must confirm the incentive effect of aid to large enterprises. Introduction[1]   In March 2019, the Court of Justice delivered […]
16. Jul 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Investor Protection and Existing Aid - StateAidHub blogpost28 Investment Romania StateAid Commission EU Lexxion

Investor Protection and Existing Aid

Aid granted before accession to the EU may not be assessed by the Commission. Introduction It is fairly safe to say that in the sixty years of case law on State aid, the Court of Justice has ruled that there are just four instances in which payment of public money to an undertaking does not constitute State aid on the […]
30. Apr 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Commission Must Explain its Decision - StateAid Blogpost17 2019 Lexxion UPS DeutschePost Eu Commission State Aid

The Commission Must Explain its Decision

A Commission decision that affects the legal position of an undertaking is actionable before EU courts. The opening of the formal investigation procedure must lead the Member State concerned to suspend the aid measure and may result in a recovery ruling by a national court. The Commission must be consistent in its reasoning. If it cannot use certain information at […]
19. Mrz 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Many Tax Rulings Do Not Make a Single Aid Scheme - StateaidHub blogpost11 Lexxion 2019 Tax Commission EU judgement

Many Tax Rulings Do Not Make a Single Aid Scheme

The autonomy that Member States enjoy in the field of direct taxation must be exercised in compliance with EU State aid law. A State aid measure is considered to be a “scheme” when (a) no further implementing acts are necessary, (b) the granting authority has no discretion in how the measure is applied and (c) the measure defines the eligible […]
29. Jan 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Services of General Economic Interest: Proper Definition and Avoidance of Overcompensation - StateAidHub Blogpost4 2019 Lexxion Stateaid SGEI Social Housing

Services of General Economic Interest: Proper Definition and Avoidance of Overcompensation

Member States need to demonstrate that public service obligations imposed on undertakings are necessary and proportional to the need for public service. A change in the funding of public services does not constitute new aid if it does not alter its objectives, the beneficiaries or the amount of aid by more than 20%.   Introduction It is a well-established principle […]
18. Dez 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Date and Scope of Public Service Compensation - SAH blog50 beneficiaries stateaid public transportation

The Date and Scope of Public Service Compensation

Aid is deemed to be granted on the date the beneficiary undertaking acquires the legal right to it, regardless of whether it is actually paid on that date. It is not enough for a public authority to define the service that it wants an operator to provide and the price that it should charge. It must also define where and […]
20. Nov 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
State Aid Provisions in the Draft Agreement on the Withdrawal of the UK from the EU - StateAid Blogpost Brexit EU Lexxion

State Aid Provisions in the Draft Agreement on the Withdrawal of the UK from the EU

The agreement on the withdrawal of the UK from the EU requires compliance with EU State aid rules.   Introduction   On 14 November 2018, EU and UK negotiators finalised the text of the Agreement on the withdrawal of the UK from the EU.[1] The Agreement has to be ratified by the UK and the other 27 Member States. Given immediate […]
21. Aug 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The European Commission’s Code of Best Practices on State Aid Procedures - SAH blogpost33 SA Code

The European Commission’s Code of Best Practices on State Aid Procedures

Closer cooperation between Commission services and Member States.   Introduction   The European Commission, DG Competition, published on 16 July 2018 on its website and then on 19 July 2018 in the Official Journal of the EU a Code of Best Practices for the Conduct of State Aid Control Procedures.[1]The purpose of the Code is to provide guidance to Member […]
25. Jun 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Remedying the Damage of a Natural Disaster through Incentives for New Investments - m 3 1

Remedying the Damage of a Natural Disaster through Incentives for New Investments

Damage from natural disasters can be remedied in the short-term through direct compensation or in the longer-term through investment subsidies to support new productive capacity.   Introduction   This article reviews a rather straightforward case which, however, is also quite unusual. It concerns a measure to remedy the effect of recent earthquakes in Italy. What makes it unusual is that […]