The Market Economy Vendor Principle: Sale of Public Land by the Dutch Municipality of Leidschendam-Voorburg [Commission Decision SA.24123]

Cadastre

The previous posting examined a case where the European Commission applied the Market Economy Investor Principle [MEIP]. This is the principle that is used to determine whether there is state aid in commercial transactions between public authorities and undertakings.

According to Article 345 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union [TFEU], the European Union is neutral with respect to the systems of property ownership in the various Member States. In practice this means that the EU does not discriminate in favour or against State-owned or private undertakings. A consequence of the neutrality stance of the EU is that in the eyes of EU law State-owned undertakings enjoy no special privilege. This is good because it prevents the State from favouring the undertakings it owns or otherwise controls.

However, the fact that the EU does not prevent Member States from owning undertakings also causes major headaches for the Commission because it cannot simply presume that capital injections or corporate acquisitions by the State distort competition. The Commission has to prove that the State distorts competition by acting differently than the typical market or private investor.

What distinguishes the State from a private investor is that the State normally pursues public policy objectives. A private investor is interested only in maximising profit from his investments. Therefore, if the State claims that it does not intend to favour the particular undertaking in which it invests, it must also be able to show that its investment can generate a return that is equivalent to what would be demanded by the typical private investor for an investment of equivalent size, duration and risk.

Commercial transactions between the State and undertakings are not limited only to capital injections and acquisition of shares. There are other kinds of transaction involving public authorities and undertakings as counterparties such as the sale of public assets. In this instance the criterion that is used by the Commission to determine the existence of aid is that of the Market Economy Vendor Principle [MEVP]. Just like in the case of MEIP where the question is whether return on investment is comparable to that required by the market, in the case of MEVP the question is whether revenue from the sale is also comparable to market level.

In 2004, the Dutch municipality of Leidschendam-Voorburg and real estate developer Schouten-de Jong Bouwfonds [SJB] set up a public-private partnership [PPP] to prepare land for a housing project. The PPP was set up in the context of a plan to redevelop the city centre. The PPP was owned 50/50 by the municipality and SJB and decisions were taken by unanimity. That is, each partner could exercise a veto. Subsequently, the municipality sold via the PPP public land to SJB. The sale agreement was concluded in 2004, but eventual payment was made in 2010. However, the price that was eventually paid was lower than the agreed price. In addition, certain fees linked to the transaction were waived. The reason for the lower sale price and the waiving of the fees was that in the meantime, as a result of the financial crisis, the price of houses that were being built also declined.

Following a complaint, the Commission opened the formal investigation procedure and in early 2013 decided that the municipality did not act as a market economy vendor, the land sale contained State aid and that the aid was incompatible with the internal market and had to be recovered.[1]

Application of the MEVP to determine the existence of State aid

The Commission began its assessment by examining the relevance of the fact that payment was finally made seven years after the agreement was concluded.

The Commission acknowledged that it was customary in Dutch construction contracts that developers could make payments for the land they purchase only when enough houses are presold. For this reason the agreement for the land sale in question included a provision for a 2.5% annual increase in the initial price until payment would be made. The Commission did not, therefore, attach any significance to the delay in payment.

This demonstrates that the existence of advantage has to be considered within the prevailing legal system of the country concerned. An unusual practice in one country may be standard in another and vice versa.

Then the Commission applied the four criteria of Article 107(1) TFEU. With respect to the transfer of state resources and imputability of the measure to the State, the Commission concluded that sale at a lower price meant loss of potential revenue. In addition, the loss could be imputed to the State because, although it was the PPP that sold the land, the municipality had the right of veto and any decision of the PPP had to be taken by unanimity.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

There was no doubt that the measure was selective and that it could affect trade and distort competition. Even though the project was local, there was active cross-border trade in the construction sector and SJB itself operated in other Member States.

The decisive element in this case was whether SJB obtained an advantage. In this respect the Dutch authorities proposed that the value of the land could be calculated by subtracting construction costs, profit and a risk provision from the value of the houses built on it. In other words, the proposed formula was:

Value of land = Price of Houses – Construction Costs – Profit – Risk Provision

The Commission rejected this ex post valuation method because it derived a “residual” value of land. The Commission explained that according to its Communication on Sale of Public Land,[2] there are two methods that create a presumption that land transactions do not contain State aid:

  1. Auctions or other open sales procedures;
  2. Ex ante valuation by independent surveyors.

 

However, following the judgment of the Court of Justice of the European Union in case C-239/09, SVA, paragraph 39, it cannot be concluded that other methods of sale necessarily contain State aid.[3] In other words, when a public authority uses an auction or ex ante independent valuation, it does not have to prove that its sale is free of State aid. However, if it uses a different method then it has to prove that the sale does not contain State aid.

So, the Commission explained that the method proposed by the Netherlands did not eliminate advantage because it started from the price of houses which was depressed by the crisis. A private vendor of land is not concerned about, nor is it liable for a decline in the value of the land after it is sold. The proposed method was transferring part of the loss from the reduction in house prices from SJB to the municipality. For this reason the measure was not MEVP compliant.

Next the Commission rejected the Dutch argument that the reduction of the sales price and the fee waiver were intended to facilitate completion of the project. Again, following the same logic as above, the Commission pointed out that the municipality was involved only at the level of ground preparation. Its liability ended at that point. Therefore, there was no need for it to share with SJB the loss from the subsequent decline in the housing market. If it did, then it would have to be compensated but it was not.

This reasoning is impeccable. A private investor or private vendor is not concerned about the value of his assets after the moment it sells them to a third person. Moreover, a private investor or vendor would not take on any additional risk without adequate monetary or otherwise compensation.

The Commission calculated the gross-grant equivalent of the State aid involved in the land sale to be EUR 6.92 million. For that purpose it used the following formula:

Amount of State aid = (2004 Sale Price + Fees, both increased by 2.5%/year for 7 years) – (2010 Payment + zero Fees) = EUR 10.92 mn – EUR 4 mn = EUR 6.92 mn

Incompatibility and recovery

The next step was to determine the compatibility of the aid with the internal market. Since none of the guidelines applied to this measure, it was assessed directly on the basis of Article 107(3)(c).

It was found not to serve an objective of common interest because the Netherlands did not show that the project was in a deprived urban area.

It was not an appropriate measure because, in response to demands from other developers for lower prices, the municipality refused and instead changed the initial planning. This proved to the Commission that measures other than State aid were available.

It was not proportional because the Commission did not accept that SJB’s contribution was relevant. The Commission explained that proportionality meant that the aid had to be proportionate to the intended policy objective, not that there was an adequate trade-off between the aid and the contribution of the beneficiary undertaking.

A finding of incompatibility was unavoidable and the Commission ordered the Netherlands to recover the aid within four months of the date of its decision.

Conclusions

This is a classic example of how public land should not be sold. If public land is sold through irregular procedures, they may confer an advantage to the purchaser. Then the compatibility of such aid is likely to be very difficult to prove in most of the old Member States which do not have assisted areas or will lose their assisted areas in the next period 2014-2020.

———————————————-

[1] Commission Decision on State aid SA.24123 (2012/C) (ex 2011/NN) implemented by the Netherlands: Alleged Sale of Land below Market Price by the Municipality of Leidschendam-Voorburg, C(2013) 87 final.

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/243459/243459_1401838_156_2.pdf

[2] Commission Communication on State Aid Elements in Sales of Land and Buildings by Public Authorities , OJ C 209, 10/07/1997, pp. 3-5

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:1997:209:0003:0005:EN:PDF

[3] Case C-239/09, Seydaland Vereinigte Agrarbetriebe GmbH & Co. KG v BVVG Bodenverwertungs- und -verwaltungs GmbH. It concerned aid granted by Germany for the acquisition of land in the framework of a programme for land privatisation and restructuring of agriculture in the new Länder.

http://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=79384&pageIndex=0&doclang=EN&mode=lst&dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=1666522

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Zusammenhängende Posts

07. Sep 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Assignment of Public Service Obligations - wordyannik mika GjFbKfI874o unsplash

Assignment of Public Service Obligations

The compensation for public service obligations may include reasonable profit and incentives for cost reduction. Introduction Member States have discretion to define services they consider to be in the general economic interest [SGEI]. However, they need to justify that definition. The Court of Justice has ruled on numerous occasions that an SGEI has “special characteristics” that set it apart from […]
18. Aug 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
MEIP-Compliant Bank Recapitalisation: CEC Bank - money 1064126 1920

MEIP-Compliant Bank Recapitalisation: CEC Bank

An investor who is already a shareholder would take into account not only the return on new investment but also the impact on the overall profitability of the company in which capital is injected. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 14 August 2020: 252* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 27; Article 107(3)(b): 211; Article […]
05. Mai 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Non-recovery of Incompatible State aid Is Costly

Legal and practical difficulties in the recovery of incompatible State aid do not constitute justifiable “absolute impossibility”. Temporary Framework On 1 May, the total number of State aid measures to combat covid-19 approved by the European Commission reached 102. Their legal basis was: Article 107(2)(b): 9; Article 107(3)(b): 86; Article 107(3)(c): 7   Introduction The 2020 Temporary Framework for State […]
27. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Identification of Undertakings in Difficulty

A company is in difficulty if, in practice, its accumulated net losses exceed 50% of its subscribed capital, regardless of whether the subscribed capital is formally written down. The classification of a company as being in difficulty is independent of the sector in which it operates and of whether a private investor would be willing to invest in it. Temporary […]
09. Apr 2020
Guest State Aid Blog von Lexxion Publisher
Woman sitting by the computer

Follow Up Webinar with Phedon Nicolaides on ‚COVID-19 and State Aid Law‘ on 20 April

The European Commission is working on quickly adapting the existing State aid legal framework to address the current Covid-19 pandemic. Join us on 20th April from the comfort and safety of your (home) office to get an insider update on the Covid-19 response by State aid experts from the European Commission and national governments. ✓ Join from wherever you are – […]
21. Feb 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
From Waste to Energy - StateAidHub blogpost7 waste to energy

From Waste to Energy

State aid to incentivise the use of waste to produce energy must be individually notified. Introduction Waste management is an increasingly important aspect of policies aiming to prevent environmental degradation and slow down climate change. As the market for recycling expands and waste management becomes more profitable, there is also a higher risk of harm to competition by State aid. […]
27. Dez 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Lexxion Publisher
5 Most Read Articles on StateAidUncovered in 2019 - 5 most read articles 2019

5 Most Read Articles on StateAidUncovered in 2019

Groundbreaking judgments like “Eesti Pagar”, applications of the private investor principle in air transport or questions of interpretation of the GBER besides many more, have moved and shaped this year’s judgments on State aid. Also Brexit and its meaning for State aid control in the UK has still been on everyone’s mind. See which articles by Prof. Phedon Nicolaides were […]
10. Dez 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Retroactive Application of the GBER - m

Retroactive Application of the GBER

When an aid scheme is adjusted by limiting the eligible beneficiaries, it becomes “new” aid and must be notified to the Commission. The GBER can be applied retroactively to aid that was granted before it came into force.   Introduction In July 2016, Dilly’s Wellnesshotel wrote legal history for being the first undertaking to contest the application of the General […]
26. Nov 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
How to Assess a Shareholder Loan - StateAidHub blogpost49 shareholder loan MEOP

How to Assess a Shareholder Loan

A shareholder loan cannot be simply compared to a bank loan because the shareholder also benefits from improvements in the future profitability of the borrower. Introduction When a public authority grants a loan to a company, the methodology in the 2008 Commission communication on reference and discount rates can be used to determine whether the loan contains State aid. However, […]
28. Aug 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Curious Case of Port Concessions - StateAidHub blogpost35 port concessions

A Curious Case of Port Concessions

The obligations of a concessionaire may be made less onerous in order to enable it to remain in operation. Any adjustment of the obligations takes into account the possible legal defences of the concessionaire. Introduction The Market Economy Investor Principle [MEIP] is a powerful concept. Its many variations attest to its versatility [e.g. market economy investor, operator, vendor, creditor]. It […]