The Curious Case of Applying the Market Economy Investor Principle to a Monopoly

monopoly game

On 3 October 2012, the European Commission concluded, in case SA.33988, that OPAP, the Greek operator of games of chance received no state aid because the Market Economy Investor Principle applied.[1] At first glance there is nothing unusual about a finding of no aid. But, as always, the devil is in the detail. OPAP holds the exclusive rights to organise various games of chance such as lotteries and betting on the outcome of football matches. In return it pays a fee to the Greek state. According to the Commission, the exclusive rights resulted in no advantage in the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU because OPAP paid a licence fee that did not allow it to earn more than the “average” company.

The MEIP compares the situation of a particular company to that of a typical market operator. If a public authority enters into a transaction with, say, company A that is more advantageous to that company than the outcome of the same transaction with the average company on the market, then company A has obtained an advantage in the meaning of Article 107(1). Such an advantage means a benefit that company A would not have been able to enjoy under normal market conditions.

The logic of the MEIP is sound. The approach is simple. It is a comparison between company A and the typical or average market operator or undertaking. The difficulty lies in identifying such a typical or average undertaking.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

The formula that is applied by the Commission compares the expected profitability or return on investment in company A with the return that a private investor would demand in order to make that investment. The return that company A is expected to generate depends on the future stream of revenue from sales of its goods or services. This future stream of revenue has to be discounted to the present day to derive its “net present value” NPV using an appropriate rate of discount. This rate is also called the “internal rate of return” (IRR).

The IRR is the rate that makes the NPV of a project or investment equal to zero. In corporate finance the IRR is regarded as the “cost” of capital for company A. This is because the cost of capital can also be thought of as a “compensation” for the private investor for the risk it assumes every time it makes an investment. There are two components to that compensation. The first is the loss of potential profit or return from not investing in alternative projects. A proxy for this potential loss is the yield on a safest investment which normally is a long-term government bond. For example, the yield on a 10-year German government bond is less than 2%. The low return indicates that investors regard it as one of the safest investments in Europe. By comparison the yield on a 10-year Greek government is above 10% and at the height of the current financial crisis it had reached over 20%.

The second component concerns the additional risk assumed by a private investor whenever it invests in a specific company. A company is normally always riskier than a government.

The IRR is calculated by discounting future revenue. The accuracy of the derived rate very much depends on the accuracy of predicting future revenue. In the case of OPAP, this was not particularly difficult because the market for games of chance is fairly stable. OPAP knew its market well as it had been organising games of chance for several decades.

By contrast the cost of capital of OPAP required a calculation of the return that the average investor would demand.

The Commission took into account a “well-documented” comparative study (not revealed for being business secret), based on the Capital Asset Pricing Model, which indicated that the Weighted Average Cost of Capital of OPAP would range between certain values (business secret). The Commission considered that that range corresponded to the maximum Internal Rate of Return (IRR) that could be left to OPAP as a “reasonable” return to avoid granting to it any economic advantage.

The Commission argued that “the presence of an economic advantage can only be excluded if the Greek State, when granting or extending exclusive rights to operate games of chance and gaming machines under the relevant arrangements, i.e. the Addendum and the VLT Agreement, leaves OPAP with the minimum return necessary for an average company to cover its operational and capital costs. By allowing OPAP to keep only such reasonable return out of the revenues generated by the operation of the games and the gaming machines, the State will ensure that the operator does not earn more (in terms of return rate) than in a normal market situation.” [Paragraphs 28-29] (emphasis added)

This case is curious because the Commission has used an approach that explicitly takes into account investment risk. Yet, OPAP was a legal monopoly. The market risk was lower if not zero. It is well-established in the case law that the presence of competition creates risk. It follows that the absence of competition must reduce risk. But if an investor in OPAP would face lower risk than otherwise, the profit or return demanded by such an investor should also be correspondingly lower. The Commission took the “average” company as a benchmark in order to determine the required cost of capital of OPAP. This must have exaggerated the cost of capital for OPAP and therefore the rate of profit that OPAP could keep. It appears that OPAP enjoyed an advantage it could not otherwise obtain from the normal operation of the market.

—————————————————————–

[1] State aid case SA.33988: Extension of OPAP’s exclusive right to operate 13 games of chance and the granting of an exclusive licence to operate Video Lottery Terminals.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Zusammenhängende Posts

18. Aug 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
MEIP-Compliant Bank Recapitalisation: CEC Bank - money 1064126 1920

MEIP-Compliant Bank Recapitalisation: CEC Bank

An investor who is already a shareholder would take into account not only the return on new investment but also the impact on the overall profitability of the company in which capital is injected. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 14 August 2020: 252* Legal basis: Article 107(2)(b): 27; Article 107(3)(b): 211; Article […]
26. Nov 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
How to Assess a Shareholder Loan - StateAidHub blogpost49 shareholder loan MEOP

How to Assess a Shareholder Loan

A shareholder loan cannot be simply compared to a bank loan because the shareholder also benefits from improvements in the future profitability of the borrower. Introduction When a public authority grants a loan to a company, the methodology in the 2008 Commission communication on reference and discount rates can be used to determine whether the loan contains State aid. However, […]
28. Aug 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Curious Case of Port Concessions - StateAidHub blogpost35 port concessions

A Curious Case of Port Concessions

The obligations of a concessionaire may be made less onerous in order to enable it to remain in operation. Any adjustment of the obligations takes into account the possible legal defences of the concessionaire. Introduction The Market Economy Investor Principle [MEIP] is a powerful concept. Its many variations attest to its versatility [e.g. market economy investor, operator, vendor, creditor]. It […]
13. Aug 2019
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Aid to Providers of Local Services through Exclusive Contracts Can still Affect Cross-border Trade - StateAidHub blogpost33 trade

Aid to Providers of Local Services through Exclusive Contracts Can still Affect Cross-border Trade

An exclusive contract can affect cross-border trade if the awarding authority has the option to use a competitive selection procedure. Aid to the operator of a legal monopoly may affect trade if the operator can cross-subsidise activities outside the area of the monopoly. Introduction A perennial question is whether aid to providers of local services can affect cross-border trade. Given […]
09. Okt 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Ex ante Assessment of Future Profitability is Absolutely Necessary - m 1 1

Ex ante Assessment of Future Profitability is Absolutely Necessary

A private investor assesses the prospects of future profitability before it invests. The burden of proof lies with the Member State that claims it has acted as a private investor.   Introduction The market economy investor principle is based on a simple premise: before you commit your money you need to check how much you are likely to get back. […]
13. Feb 2018
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Investment in Airport Infrastructure - ashim d silva pGcqw1ARGyg unsplash

Investment in Airport Infrastructure

Public funding of infrastructure used for non-economic purposes does not constitute State aid. Public investment in infrastructure used for economic purposes does not constitute State aid if the investment can generate a return that is acceptable to a private investor.   Introduction   On 25 January 2018, the General Court ruled in case T-818/14, Brussels South Charleroi Airport v Commission.[1] Brussels […]
05. Dez 2017
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Imputability of an Aid Measure to the State Does not Require a Counterfactual - 05.12.Imputability of Aid State aidz

Imputability of an Aid Measure to the State Does not Require a Counterfactual

The fact that the state owns an undertaking is not enough to prove that the decisions of that undertaking can be attributed to the state. However, it is sufficient that the state was involved in the particular decision that transferred state resources for the benefit of another undertaking.   Introduction Several recent articles on this blog have examined the concept […]
29. Aug 2017
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Bank Recapitalisation that Conforms to the Market Economy Investor Principle - m 7

Bank Recapitalisation that Conforms to the Market Economy Investor Principle

A public authority acts like a private investor when it injects capital in a stricken bank if there is a realistic prospect of sufficient return that compensates it for the risk it bears.   Introduction Caixa Geral de Depósitos (CGD) is the largest bank in Portugal and is now fully owned by the State. In June 2012, Portugal notified to […]
20. Jun 2017
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Effectiveness of Clear Guidance: The Case of Broadband Networks - m 13

The Effectiveness of Clear Guidance: The Case of Broadband Networks

This blog examines how much aid goes to support broadband networks and what lessons can be drawn from the Commission’s decisional practice.   Introduction A principal objective of the State Aid Modernisation was to free Commission resources from the time-consuming task of checking the conformity of routine measures of State aid. Consequently, the General Block Exemption Regulation was extended to […]
01. Mrz 2016
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
How to Apply the Market Economy Investor Principle and what Mistakes to Avoid: The Long-running Case of EDF - 17.10. imputability stateaid

How to Apply the Market Economy Investor Principle and what Mistakes to Avoid: The Long-running Case of EDF

A market investor carries out a thorough ex ante analysis of the prospects of an investment before it commits any money.     Introduction In 2004, the European Commission concluded, in decision 2005/145, that France granted incompatible aid to Electricite de France [EDF]. The French government had converted tax liability into share capital in EDF. The Commission was of the […]