Nature Conservation as a Service of General Economic Interest

Nature Conservation as a Service of General Economic Interest - m 38

Public funding of non-economic activities does not create State aid problems when any related economic activities are clearly separated. The 2012 SGEI package can apply retroactively.

 

Introduction

Member States of the European Union are free to designate the services they consider to be in the general economic interest. However, the wide discretion they enjoy in this respect falls under the scrutiny of the Commission which checks for “manifest error”. It is difficult to know when a Member State commits a manifest error in this context. This is because the concept of manifest error with respect to SGEI has not been defined in the case law. However, from cases where EU courts have agreed with the Commission’s views, we can infer that Member States commit a manifest error when they do not justify why a service is in the general interest or when they do not ensure that such a service is provided to all the citizens who are supposed to need it.

Normally, an SGEI is a service which is needed in everyday life such as communications, energy, water distribution or postal delivery. Commission decision SA.27301 on subsidised acquisition of land in the Netherlands deals with an unusual case of SGEI.[1] The Netherlands considered that nature conservation was an SGEI. This is not only unusual with regard to the scope of the SGEI but also unusual with regard to the recipients of the SGEI. Normally an SGEI is delivered to citizens. Maintaining a natural landscape may be in the broad social interest but it can hardly be defined as a service which is “consumed” by citizens.

Background

In 2008 the Commission received a complaint concerning subsidies granted by the Netherlands to thirteen beneficiaries for the acquisition of land for nature conservation. The beneficiaries were foundations whose purpose was to protect natural landscapes. The Netherlands claimed that the subsidies did not confer any advantage because the activities of the beneficiaries were not economic. However, if the beneficiaries could be deemed to have obtained an advantage, the subsidies constituted compensation for public service obligations. Therefore, the issues at hand were whether land conservation was an economic activity, if not, whether it could be considered as a service of general economic interest and, if yes, whether the thirteen organisations in question derived an advantage.

Nature Conservation as a Service of General Economic Interest - Banner Energy Hub

Nature conservation

The thirteen organisations, whose name in Dutch is abbreviated as TBO [loosely translated as Nature Management Organisations (NMO)], received subsidies to buy or lease land in order to protect it and manage it. The status of the NMOs as “foundations” prevents them from making profit. They achieved their mission by setting land aside and by managing land-based activities such as wood cutting and clearing and by selling land-based products, issuing fishing permits and operating camping sites.

Non-economic activities, ancillary activities and economic activities

As mentioned above, the Netherlands first argued that the NMOs were not undertakings because they were non-profit, their main task was nature conservation and that their secondary activities which generated revenue, are marginal and intrinsically linked to their core task of nature conservation.

The Commission accepted that NMOs were not involved in economic activities when they were carrying out their nature conservation tasks. Indeed the Commission referred extensively to the judgment in case T-347/09, Germany v Commission, which confirmed that nature conservation was based on solidarity and was not an economic activity.

However, the Commission pointed out that other activities of the NMOs were economic and therefore, they became undertakings by the mere fact that they were partly involved in economic transactions such as selling wood and offering camping or fishing facilities.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

One would have thought that since the economic activities were secondary or ancillary, they could be either fenced off through separate accounting or, if they were less than 20% of the total capacity of the NMOs, they could be subsumed in the main non-economic activities. The problem was that the relevant Dutch law “(49) […] did not ex ante and in an exhaustive manner define the secondary economic activities that could be performed on the acquired land besides nature conservation. (50) While it cannot be excluded that some of these activities, as the Dutch authorities submit, were purely ancillary to the main task of nature

conservation, at least part of the secondary activities, like tourism, involved economic activities. In this regard reference is made to the same judgment of the General Court mentioned above, where it was concluded that activities of nature conservation organizations, similar to those of the [NMOs], can be deemed to be economic activities, not necessarily linked to nature conservation.”

In view of the significance that the concept of ancillarity has acquired since the adoption of the new GBER and R&D&I rules in 2014, the Commission seems to be making the following important clarification. An ancillary activity, which on its own is economic in nature, can be considered to be non-economic when it is necessarily linked to a non-economic activity. In this case, the management of land requires wood felling and wood clearing. The waste wood then has to be disposed. Selling it as fire wood or for other purposes is an economic activity which, however, is inextricably linked and necessary to the main task of nature conservation. Operating a camping site is not inextricably linked to nature conservation. On the other hand, hunting or fishing can under certain conditions be linked to management of wildlife. The additional factor which is brought into consideration by the Commission, without however explaining its significance, is the requirement for the relevant law to list “secondary” economic activities “exhaustively”. The Commission appears to be using secondary and ancillary interchangeably without clarifying whether they are different or the same. But it also seems to consider as ancillary those secondary activities which are linked to the primary non-economic tasks. At any rate, the R&D&I framework which refers to ancillary activities does not require their exhaustive listing.

Economic advantage

The Netherlands also argued that the NMOs did not derive any advantage. The response of the Commission was that they did receive an advantage because “(55) […] the land was put free of charge or at reduced cost at the disposal of the [NMOs] who could obtain revenues from its use.”

The Netherlands was of the view that i) the revenues did not exceed costs and ii) if the revenues exceeded the eligible costs, the balance had to be reinvested in nature conservation or transferred to the state. Again the Commission, correctly, rejected this view because “(55) […] even if the use of the revenues was limited, [the measure in question] […] provided the beneficiaries with an advantage compared to other companies that needed to invest in nature land to carry out similar economic activities.” There was also an advantage in that the NMOs “(56) […] could receive an economic advantage through capital gains made when they resold the acquired land”.

The Commission could have added that the NMOs benefitted not just from obtaining assets for free but also from not having to finance the acquisition of those assets [e.g. they avoided the cost of borrowing to buy land].

Compatibility of the aid

The Commission accepted that the aid could be considered as a compensation for the extra costs of services of general economic interest. It examined its compatibility on the basis of the 2012 SEIG framework. But before it did that it rejected a proposal by the Dutch authorities concerning the legal basis of assessment.

The Netherlands suggested that the aid could be exempted on the basis of the cultural heritage exception in Article 53(2)(b) GBER. The Commission rejected it because “(70) […] the scheme was limited to the 13 [NMOs] individually enumerated in Article 3 of the central regulation, which are all Dutch, and thus the scheme was discriminatory and in breach of Article 1(5)(a) GBER.”

Nature Conservation as a Service of General Economic Interest - Banner Paris

Indeed Article 1(5)(a) of the GBER stipulates the following:

“5. This Regulation shall not apply to State aid measures, which entail, by themselves, by the conditions attached to them or by their financing method a non-severable violation of Union law, in particular:

(a) aid measures where the grant of aid is subject to the obligation for the beneficiary to have its headquarters in the relevant Member State or to be predominantly established in that Member State; However, the requirement to have an establishment or branch in the aid granting Member State at the moment of payment of the aid is allowed.”

The Commission interpreted the ex ante listing of the beneficiaries to be equivalent to an obligation to be headquartered in the Netherlands.

Then it explained that because the 2005 SGEI rules do not apply retroactively [the Dutch measure dated back to 1993], it would assess the measure on the basis of the 2012 SGEI rules which do apply retroactively.

Genuine SGEI?

The first step in applying the SGEI rules is to establish that a service is indeed in the general economic interest. The Commission analysis, however, is a bit puzzling. It says, “(74) […] nature conservation may constitute a service of general interest (SGI). The costs incurred by this activity exceed its revenues, being based on solidarity, and thus nature conservation does not offer any incentive for the market to provide it.”

The puzzling aspect is that for a service to be considered as an SGEI, it must be economic in nature. In the quoted sentence above, there is only reference to SGI, which is non-economic. This is reinforced by the acknowledgment in the same sentence that the service was based on “solidarity”. This is a typical characteristic of a non-economic activity. By contrast, the revenue obtained by the NMOs was not from selling SGEI to the public but from providing economic activities [e.g. tourism]. The Commission bypassed this problem by deciding to examine the compatibility of compensation through a “global approach” and “global analysis” of all revenues [paragraphs 75-76]. It is as if the Commission bundled together a non-economic activity with some economic activities in order to produce an SGEI. Perhaps this strange arrangement was the only means by which the aid could be found compatible with the internal market.

The compatibility assessment was carried out not on the basis of the 2012 decision but on the 2012 framework. The reason was that the decision, which is like a block exemption regulation, imposes a limit of EUR 15 million on maximum compensation and it applies to measures which have limited duration. The Dutch scheme was of unlimited duration and the aid could have exceeded the threshold of EUR 15 million.

It is important to note that, according to the Commission, the retroactive application of the 2012 framework meant that the following provisions of the framework did not apply:

Point 14: the requirement for public consultation.

Point 19: compliance with public procurement rules.

Point 20: the requirement for absence of discrimination in the assignment of the public service obligation.

Point 24: application of the net avoided cost methodology.

Point 39: the requirement for efficiency incentives.

Point 60: the requirement for transparency.

The Commission assessed compliance with the remaining requirements of the 2012 SGEI framework as follows.

Entrustment

“(85) An act of entrustment […] should spell out the nature of the task as well as the scope and the general operational conditions of the SGEI.

(86) [the aid was] conditional upon respecting special nature conservation PSOs which were set out in detail for the purchased land.

(87) Detailed rules were also established in the award decisions regarding the management subsidies granted for nature conservation purposes for the acquired land”.

With respect to the duration of entrustment, the Commission notes that “(89) generally, the objective of the SGEI Framework provision regarding the limited duration of entrustment is to ensure that the State reviews the market situation regularly to ensure that maintaining a public service is justified and to allow competition for the granting of the public service concerned through the application of public procurement rules.” Although the entrustment in the past was unlimited, the Commission requested the Netherlands to limit it in the future.

Amount of compensation

“(92) […] The secondary economic activities of the beneficiaries consumed the same inputs as the ones necessary for nature conservation, using the same infrastructure and equipment: same nature land and tools such as wood cutting or grass mowing machines, same labour force (volunteers) and same capital.

(93) In light of the above, in the present case, both the primary activity of nature conservation and the revenue-generating secondary activities are considered to fall within the scope of the global SGEI. For the purposes of analysing the amount of compensation, all costs and revenues borne by the [NMOs] are taken into account, by setting the costs and revenues of the secondary economic activities of the [NMOs] against the costs borne for nature conservation.

(96) […] The Dutch authorities explained that nature conservation is a loss-making activity and provided further detailed information, confirming that revenues from nature conservation management were deducted from the management subsidies. The information provided shows that the costs borne by nature conservation were higher than the revenues generated by the land through any secondary economic activity that could be carried out on it. Considering that account was taken of the revenue generated from nature conservation by the [NMOs], it can be concluded that there was no risk of overcompensation through income resulting from secondary economic activities carried out on the nature land purchased under the measure in question.”

On the basis of the above reasoning, the Commission concluded that the aid was compatible with Article 106(2) TFEU.

—————————————————————————————-

[1] The full text of the Commission decision can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/cases/259133/259133_1708634_151_2.pdf.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

03. Dez 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for Non-payment of State Aid Can Constitute State Aid - State Aid Uncovered photos 24

Compensation for Non-payment of State Aid Can Constitute State Aid

Introduction A perennial question by aggrieved investors who feel cheated by u-turns in public policy is: “May I claim compensation for damage that I have suffered as a result of non-payment of the State aid that was promised to me?” As a result of recent case law, it is now clear that there are several answers to this question: First, […]
26. Nov 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
i) Compensation Can Be State Aid ii) Failure to Act - State Aid Uncovered photos 23

i) Compensation Can Be State Aid ii) Failure to Act

Introduction This article reviews two judgments concerning a claim that compensation does not constitute State aid and a complaint that the Commission had failed to act, respectively. The latter case is particularly interesting because it is probably the only judgment in the past decade or two that the Court of Justice has actually upheld a claim that the Commission breached […]
29. Okt 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
An Unusual SGEI - State Aid Uncovered photos 16

An Unusual SGEI

Introduction Member States are free to determine what the regard as a service of general economic interest [SGEI]. The Commission may only check whether the definition is free of manifest error and that any compensation that is provided conforms with the conditions laid down in the 2012 SGEI package. Member States commit a manifest error when they designate as SGEI […]
10. Sep 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for Switching to a New Broadcasting Frequency - State Aid Uncovered photos 10

Compensation for Switching to a New Broadcasting Frequency

Introduction Normally the cost of compliance with mandatory regulations may not be offset, partially or fully, by State aid because it lacks incentive effect. The beneficiaries would have to incur those costs anyway. However, even in the case of mandatory compliance, State aid may still have an incentive effect if the undertakings concerned would cease altogether the activity in question. […]
30. Jul 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
State Aid Measures May not Infringe EU Law outside the Field of State Aid - State Aid Uncovered photos 5

State Aid Measures May not Infringe EU Law outside the Field of State Aid

Introduction In December 2020, the Commission approved State aid scheme SA.59029 by which Italy compensated airlines for damage they had suffered as a result of covid-19-related restrictions, in the period from 1 March to 15 June 2020. Eligible airlines were only those that were licensed in Italy. The aid was approved on the basis of Article 107(2)(b) TFEU. In May […]
17. Okt 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for Damage - Untitled design 10

Compensation for Damage

Introduction On 28 September 2023, the Court of Justice, in case C-320/21 P, Ryanair v European Commission, delivered its first judgment in a series of appeals brought by Ryanair challenging the dismissal by the General Court of its action in multiple cases seeking the annulment of various Commission decisions authorising aid to airlines during the covid-19 pandemic. Both before the […]
28. Dez 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Consequences of not Knowing when State Aid is State Aid - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 15

The Consequences of not Knowing when State Aid is State Aid

Introduction Public officials, legal advisors and academics are sometimes frustrated by the practice of the Commission of declaring a public measure as being compatible with the internal market without first taking a firm position on whether that measure constitutes State aid. The Commission would say something like “it is not certain whether the aided activity is economic in nature” or […]
29. Nov 2022
von Phedon Nicolaides
What Costs Must be Included in Compensation for Public Service Obligations? - State Aid Uncovered SM posts

What Costs Must be Included in Compensation for Public Service Obligations?

Introduction The two most difficult issues in imposing a public service obligation on a providers of a service of general economic interest is, first, the correct definition of the obligation and, second, the correct calculation of the amount of compensation that covers only the net extra cost of the service. The correct definition must take into account what the market […]
08. Nov 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Natural Disasters and State Aid - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 4

Natural Disasters and State Aid

Compensation for damage suffered by undertakings as a result of a natural disaster constitutes State aid. The compensation is compatible with the internal market only if, first, there is a causal relationship between the natural disaster and the damage and, second, the amount of compensation does not exceed the amount of the damage. Introduction Financial assistance in the form of […]
23. Aug 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part II) - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 18 1

Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part II)

Public service obligations must be imposed through an act of entrustment that defines clearly the terms of the service and the duration of the obligation. The “reasonable profit” in the public service compensation should reflect the risk borne by the provider. Introduction In 2009, the Commission received several complaints concerning State aid that Italy had granted to the various shipping […]