The New Guidelines on State Aid to Airports and Airlines (part 1)

man looking airplane takeoff

Introduction[1]

One more set of State aid rules for 2014-20 has been adopted. On Thursday, 20 February 2014, the Commission published its Guidelines on State Aid to Airports and Airlines.[2] The other main substantive rules which are already in place are the following, in chronological order:[3]

  1. The package on services of general economic interest (SGEI): A Communication, a Decision (like a block exemption regulation), a Framework and a de minimis Regulation [December 2011 – April 2012].
  2. Guidelines on broadband networks [December 2012].
  3. Guidelines on regional aid [June 2013].
  4. The de minimis Regulation [December 2013].
  5. Guidelines on risk finance [January 2014].

In this article I review the new Guidelines on airports and airlines and I identify the improvements in relation to the Guidelines they replaced, but also weaknesses concerning some points that should have been more carefully explained.

The new Guidelines reflect the experience of the Commission in dealing with more than 100 cases concerning public funding of airports and/or airlines. The funding of airlines may also be indirect, as they may benefit from access to subsidised infrastructure and/or lower fees charged by State-owned airports. It is telling that the majority of airports in Europe are public and about 40% of all airports are loss-making.

The novel features of the Guidelines on State Aid to Airports and Airlines

The new Guidelines start with an explanation of how the concept of State aid applies to airport infrastructure, airport operators and airlines. This was a feature in the 2005 Guidelines too, but in the new Guidelines the explanation is more detailed and covers the latest legal developments such as the Leipzig-Halle judgment.

The Guidelines also bring up to date the treatment of financial relationships between airports and airlines, especially in relation to the market economy operator test [MEOT].

Another novel feature is that they come with four neat tables that summarise all the main provisions of the Guidelines. The tables also summarise the application of the common assessment principles.

Lastly, the new Guidelines explain how the rules of the new SGEI package apply to airports and airlines and especially how an SGEI can be defined in this sector.

Economic v non-economic activities

The new Guidelines devote three pages to clarifying the distinction between economic and non-economic activities. Most of what is written there has already been included in the still draft Communication on the concept of State aid. In addition to shedding light to the dividing line between economic and non-economic activities, the Guidelines also deal with the important issue of the prevention of cross-subsidisation between the two types of activity.

In this connection, the Guidelines warn that “overcompensation of non-economic activities may constitute State aid” [paragraph 36]. It is not explained, however, why it is presumed, in the presence of account separation, that overcompensation can benefit economic activities.

The Guidelines also contain a statement that at first glance appears to be cryptic but on reflection is quite important. It concerns paragraph 37 which I quote in full:

“Public financing of non-economic activities must not lead to undue discrimination between airports. Indeed, it is established case law that there is an advantage when public authorities relieve undertakings of the costs inherent to their economic activities. Therefore, when it is normal under a given legal order that airports have to bear certain costs inherent to the operation of a civil airport, whereas other airports do not, the latter may be granted an advantage, regardless of whether or not those costs relate to an activity, which in general is considered to be of a non-economic nature.”


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

To understand the significance of this statement, we need to consider the relevant legal background. The Court of Justice explained in GEMO [C-126/01] that an undertaking derives an advantage from State intervention when it is relieved from the costs which are “inherent” in its operations. In the GEMO case, France had argued that it funded the disposal of animal carcasses because it had imposed a public service obligation on farmers and slaughterhouses. The Court rejected this argument, despite the fact that Member States are at liberty to define public service obligation [PSO] and SGEI. The reasoning of the Court was impeccable. The production of animal carcasses is inherent in animal husbandry and slaughtering. Therefore, farmers and slaughterhouses were responsible to dispose them properly. They would do that anyway and therefore there was no need to impose any obligation on them. Moreover, what is inherent is also determined by the legal obligations of undertakings in any given national system. For example, it is normal [because the law says so] for undertakings to bear the costs of one-year sick leave in the Netherlands, while in other countries the responsibility of employers may end after a 30 days. Then, the sick employee who cannot work is passed on the social security system.

The Commission appears to apply the GEMO logic to airport operations. Airports must bear the costs which are generated by their operations. These costs are determined by the legal obligations of undertakings in a given system. Furthermore, Member States must be consistent. If they ask or expect an airport to cover certain costs itself, they cannot claim that similar costs incurred by other airports can be covered by the State.

The Commission also implies that what is economic or non-economic depends on the legal order of each Member State. For example, in a given Member State all security aspects may fall within the remit of the State, while in other Member States they may be divided in those that belong to the responsibility of the State [e.g. armed guards] and those that may be carried out by airport personnel [e.g. checking luggage].

Lastly and for the sake of completeness, one may ask whether costs which are inherent in the operations of an airport can ever be considered to be non-economic. After all, according to the GEMO logic, inherent costs are those that are necessarily generated by the operation of an airport. Therefore, inherent costs must be economic in nature. I suppose some of these costs, such as fire-fighting services and equipment which are normally classified as non-economic, can in principle be covered by airports themselves. However, certain other costs, such as those concerning security, immigration and customs, are linked to the operations of airports because governments stipulate so without being strictly necessary for airports to function. Airport operators do not care who enters the country or what they carry with them. But because governments want to enforce public policies such as those on immigration and customs at the border and because airport operators cannot enforce policies which depend on the exercise of State prerogatives, their enforcement has become inextricable with the operation of airports with governments picking up the costs. Therefore, in practice certain costs are considered to be non-economic despite the fact that they are also presumed to be inherent to the operation of airports because they are linked to that operation by decisions of the State.

At any rate, the important points to note are the following two. First, it is up to each Member State to define the non-economic aspects of airport operations [provided that their funding does not cross-subsidise commercial activities (and provided that they comply with the requirements of the case law)] and, second, Member States must treat all airports in their territory in the same way.

Aid v non-aid [MEOT]

The Guidelines also explain how the granting of aid may be avoided in commercial arrangements between airports and airlines. This is when these arrangements satisfy the market economy operator test [MEOT]. Since many airports are State-owned, it is indeed possible that they may not charge fees at commercial rates which are MEOT compliant. The Commission identifies two methods for determining whether arrangements between airports are airlines are free of State aid.

The first is the benchmark method whereby the fees charged by an airport are compared to those charged by others. But the Commission largely dismisses this method because most airports are subsidised and many are loss-making. So their fees cannot be taken as a robust indicator that they cover all relevant costs.

The second method is the incremental costing of airport fees. At paragraph 61, the Guidelines reveal that “the Commission considers ex ante incremental profitability analysis to be the most relevant criterion for the assessment of arrangements concluded by airports with individual airlines.”

Paragraph 64 explains that fees must cover the incremental costs borne by airports. “In order to assess whether an arrangement concluded by an airport with an airline complies with the MEO test, expected non-aeronautical revenues stemming from the airline’s activity should be taken into consideration together with airport charges, net of any rebates, marketing support or incentive schemes. Similarly, all expected costs incrementally incurred by the airport in relation to the airline’s activity at the airport should be taken into account. Such incremental costs could encompass all categories of expenses or investments, such as incremental personnel, equipment and investment costs induced by the presence of the airline at the airport. For instance, if the airport needs to expand or build a new terminal or other facilities mainly to accommodate the needs of a specific airline, such costs should be taken into consideration when calculating the incremental costs. In contrast, costs which the airport would have to incur anyway independently from the arrangement with the airline should not be taken into account in the MEO test”.

This formulation of what should go into calculating airline fees is very important. It says that airports can take into account all sources of revenue, including “non-aeronautical” items such as income from parking or shopping. We will see immediately below that State aid is not allowed under these Guidelines to support non-aeronautical activities. Yet, airports are allowed to take into account revenue from non-eligible activities.

The Guidelines in a nutshell

Purpose of aid

Aid may be granted for the following purposes:

  • Airports:
    a) Investment in airport infrastructure.
    b) Operations of airports [operating aid].
  • Start-up aid to airlines.
  • Social aid to particular groups of citizens.
  • SGEI.

Investment aid to airport infrastructure

In principle investment aid is allowed only for airports with annual traffic of less than 3 million passengers. The eligible costs are limited to infrastructure, buildings and equipment [excluding costs such as those for the construction of parking, shops, etc]. The aid intensity depends on passenger traffic and ranges from 25% to 75%. [It should be noted that if the airport is located in an assisted area, the costs which are non-eligible under the airport/airline Guidelines (e.g. parking facilities) may be eligible under the Regional Aid Guidelines.]

Operating aid to airports

It is allowed only for airports with fewer than 3 million passengers per year. Operating aid may be granted only for a period of 10 years and may cover only up to 50% of the operating funding gap [see below].

Start-up to airlines

Aid may be granted only for the launch of new routes from airports with annual passenger traffic of less than 3 million passengers. The eligible costs are the relevant airport charges and maximum aid intensity is 50% of those charges.

Social aid

This kind of aid may be granted only to specific groups of citizens with well identified needs, such as for example, elderly, low income or disabled persons and residents of remote regions. The aid must be open to any airline. No maximum aid intensity is defined.

SGEI

The Guidelines do not lay down new rules. The applicable rules are those in the 2012 SGEI package. But the Guidelines provide useful explanation of how an SGEI may be defined in relation to air transportation. For air transport services, an SGEI has to be defined in conformity with the provisions of Regulation 1008/2008 on common rules for the operation of air services in the EU. A PSO can be imposed only for specific routes which are not adequately served by the market and for which there are no alternative means of transport in their catchment area. For airports, a PSO may be imposed only when a particular region would be isolated without the airport. This could be the case for outermost regions defined in Article 349 TFEU and islands. The compatibility of aid to support an SGEI is assessed either on the basis of the SGEI Decision [Decision 2012/21] for airports with fewer than 200,000 passengers and airlines linking islands with fewer than 300,000 passengers or the SGEI Framework for airports and airlines with larger annual volumes.

In the article next week, I will examine three issues which, I believe, are not well explained by the Guidelines.

 


[1] I am grateful to Mihalis Kekelekis and Peter Staviczky for comments on a previous draft.

[2] The Guidelines can be accessed at:

http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/modernisation/aviation_guidelines_en.pdf

[3] In addition, there are rules on short-term export credit and State aid to the film sector.

Tags

About

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Related Posts

29. Oct 2024
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
An Unusual SGEI - State Aid Uncovered photos 16

An Unusual SGEI

Introduction Member States are free to determine what the regard as a service of general economic interest [SGEI]. The Commission may only check whether the definition is free of manifest error and that any compensation that is provided conforms with the conditions laid down in the 2012 SGEI package. Member States commit a manifest error when they designate as SGEI […]
23. Apr 2024
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Pricing of Access to Infrastructure for the Treatment of Waste Water - State Aid Uncovered photos 10

Pricing of Access to Infrastructure for the Treatment of Waste Water

Introduction It is not unusual for EU courts to refer to the Commission’s 2016 Notice on the Notion of State Aid as a means of shedding light to the more obscure aspects of that notion. What is very unusual is for EU courts to treat the Notice as if it has the same status as the guidelines that bind the […]
01. Aug 2023
by Phedon Nicolaides
Profitability as a Criterion of the Compatibility of State Aid with the Internal Market - Untitled design 4

Profitability as a Criterion of the Compatibility of State Aid with the Internal Market

Introduction When the state has a realistic prospect of making profit, its financial transactions with third parties do not constitute State aid. The absence of profit is a strong indicator of the presence of State aid but not necessarily its compatibility with the internal market. For State aid to be compatible with the internal market it must, among other things, […]
03. Jul 2023
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART II) - Untitled design 17

Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART II)

Introduction When public authorities buy goods and services for themselves, they have to pay a market price, otherwise they confer an abnormal advantage to the sellers. On 14 June 2023, the General Court, in case T‑79/21, Ryanair & Airport Marketing Services v European Commission, ruled that public authorities still confer an abnormal advantage by buying good and services that they […]
27. Jun 2023
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART I) - Untitled design 3 1

Transactions at Market Rates Can still Confer an Advantage that Constitutes State aid (PART I)

Introduction When public authorities buy goods and services for themselves, they have to pay a market price, otherwise they confer an abnormal advantage to the sellers. On 14 June 2023, the General Court, in case T-79/21, Ryanair & Airport Marketing Services v European Commission, ruled that public authorities still confer an abnormal advantage by buying good and services that they […]
25. Jan 2022
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Duplication of Infrastructure Does not Promote Regional Development - Social Media posts 6

Duplication of Infrastructure Does not Promote Regional Development

A private investor is not interested in regional development. A private investor recoups its investment in infrastructure from revenue from the operation of that infrastructure. Duplication of infrastructure does not contribute to regional development. Introduction In 2015 the European Commission caused a buzz in the State aid community when it decided that investment aid granted to a small Polish airport […]
30. Nov 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Public Funding of an Undertaking in a Closed Sector - Blog Visual 48

Public Funding of an Undertaking in a Closed Sector

Public funding of undertakings in sectors closed to competition does not constitute State aid. A sector is closed to competition when competition on and for the market is precluded by law. Introduction Determining when State aid does not affected cross-border trade is both difficult and tricky. But there is one exception; when the sector is closed to competition. A sector […]
12. Oct 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Security of Supply May Justify a Deviation from Public Procurement Rules - Blog visual 41

Security of Supply May Justify a Deviation from Public Procurement Rules

Security of supply justifies a deviation from the normal procurement procedures as long as the same security cannot be achieved through a competitive selection of suppliers. Introduction Point 19 of the 2012 SGEI Framework requires that the assignment of a public mission to an undertaking must comply with the applicable public procurement rules. It does not impose an obligation for […]
21. Sep 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Market Economy Operator Test: Timisoara Airport & Wizz Air - 38 pexels anugrah lohiya 723240

Market Economy Operator Test: Timisoara Airport & Wizz Air

Public funding of activities that fall within the remit of the state does not constitute state aid. Although the presence of a credible ex ante business plan based on realistic assumptions is a strong indicator that the MEOT is satisfied, its absence does not necessarily prove that the MEOT is failed. Introduction Following a complaint by Carpatair, the European Commission […]
07. Sep 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Assignment of Public Service Obligations - wordyannik mika GjFbKfI874o unsplash

Assignment of Public Service Obligations

The compensation for public service obligations may include reasonable profit and incentives for cost reduction. Introduction Member States have discretion to define services they consider to be in the general economic interest [SGEI]. However, they need to justify that definition. The Court of Justice has ruled on numerous occasions that an SGEI has “special characteristics” that set it apart from […]