Benchmarks of Profitability for Private Investors

movie production
A public authority that injects capital in an undertaking [or provides any other kind of finance] must ensure that the funding can achieve the rate of return that can, in principle, satisfy a private investor. The rate that can satisfy a private investor and ensure that the funding is free of State aid is the rate that covers the cost of capital for that particular investment. It is not necessary that the expected rate of return maximises profit or achieves the highest possible return among all investment opportunities.

Introduction
 
In this article I review the judgement of the General Court in joined cases T-319/12 and T-321/12, Spain v Commission.[1] Spain appealed against Commission Decision 2013/126 concerning State aid to film studios Ciudad de la Luz. This is a good example of how it can be determined whether injections of public capital contain State aid. This is also an excellent example of why it is almost impossible that State aid in the form of capital injection can be found to be compatible with the internal market, if it is not explicitly designed for that purpose. This is because such capital injection becomes operating aid that is normally not intended to fit into any of the categories of exemption in the second or third paragraph of Article 107.The project undertaken by Ciudad de la Luz

The Autonomous Community of Valencia (Spain) decided to invest in the creation of film studio Ciudad de la Luz [CDL], near Alicante. CDL was created in November 2000 with a registered capital of EUR 600,000. Its share capital was initially held at 75% by the Autonomous Community of Valencia. The rest of the capital was held by the private production company Aguamarga whose task was to manage and promote the studios.

Between November 2001 and May 2004, the share capital of the CDL was increased three times. All shares of Aguamarga were bought out in July 2004. CDL was 100% owned by the Community of Valencia.

Following complaints, the Commission assessed the capital injections and concluded that they did not conform with the private investor principle. It further found that they constituted incompatible aid that had to be repaid.

The main arguments of the applicants focused on how the Commission applied the principle of private investor and whether aid was compatible with the internal market.

Existence of State aid and application of the private investor principle

The General Court, in its judgment of 3 July 2014, acknowledged at the outset that the Commission had wide discretion when examining complex measures.

With respect to the threshold of profitability that must be achieved by the hypothetical private investor, the applicants were of the view that the Commission should have compared the profitability of CDL with the average yield of the sector.

The Court first noted that the Commission did not use the average rate of return in the sector in order to assess the profitability of CDL in its application of the criterion of the private investor. In fact the Commission compared the projected yield of the studio with the opportunity cost of capital. The cost of capital was calculated according to the capital asset pricing model [CAPM]. [paragraph 38] On the basis of the CAPM, the cost of capital is derived from the following formula: K = Rf + (Rm – Rf)β, where K is the cost of capital, Rf is the risk-free rate [usually that of government bonds], Rm is the average market return, and β is a coefficient that indicates how a specific share fluctuates in relation to the market.


Do you know we also publish a journal on State aid?

EStAL banner
The European State Aid Law Quarterly is available online and in print, and our subscribers benefit from a reduced price for our events.


 

The Court, however, also acknowledged that the case law does not require that the hypothetical private investor achieves the highest possible return of all investment opportunities in the economy or even in the particular sector. What the case law requires is only consideration whether it would be economically rational for a private investor to commit his money in the particular project. Moreover, the behaviour of a private investor, which should be compared with that of a public investor is not necessarily that of an ordinary investor pursuing short-term profit. The relevant benchmark of behaviour must be that of a private holding company pursuing a structural policy and is guided by prospects of profitability in the longer term [paragraphs 39-41] the Court cited the following cases to support this position: SFEI, C-39/94; WestLB, T-228/99; Belgium v Commission, C-142/87; Italy v Commission, C-305/89; Cityflyer Express v Commission, T-16/96.

The Commission, according to the Court, is entitled to use, in the context of the application of Article 107(1), the value of the average return in the sector as an analytical instrument among others to determine whether the recipient undertaking obtains an economic advantage which it would not have available to it under normal market conditions. Moreover, the use of average industry performance does not relieve the Commission of its obligation to make a complete analysis all relevant elements of the transaction at issue and its context [paragraphs 42-45].

In response to the argument that the Commission had used such an average return in other cases, the Court explained that State aid is an objective concept that is applied to the facts of each case. The classification of a measure as State aid cannot depend on a subjective assessment by the Commission and must be determined independently of any previous administrative practice of the Commission [Freistaat Sachsen v Commission, C-57/00 P; Regione Autonoma della Sardegna v Commission, T-171/02] [paragraph 46].

With respect to the method for establishing whether the project was sufficiently profitable, the Court, first, accepted that the Commission correctly ignored the investment of Aguamarga. This was because it had invested not as an investor for seeking profit in the longer term but as a service provider who provided working capital in the initial phases of the project.

Second, it rejected the argument that there was no State aid because public authorities were guided by independent reports. Indeed, a private investor must determine the profitability of the project on an ex ante basis, but the General Court stressed that no case law establishes that the existence of independent reports is sufficient for excluding the existence of State aid. Member States must still decide whether the reports are appropriate and correct.

Third, Valencia should have been more critical vis-à-vis the findings of the independent reports. According to the Commission, the cost of capital stood at 16.7% in 2000 and 14.9% in 2004. It then compared the cost of capital with the IRR of the project. A private investor would have been willing to invest in CDL only if the expected internal rate of return were greater than or equal to the cost of capital. In order to compare the cost of capital and the internal rate of return, the Commission took over the internal rate of return of 8.8% in 2000 and 5.7% in 2004. As a result, with a cost of capital of 14.9%, the net present value of the project led to a loss of about EUR 130 million euros. The Commission also conducted reliability analyses of the robustness of the results. The Court accepted this approach as a valid method for determining whether a private investor would inject capital in the project. By contrast Valencia did not carry out such an assessment with the same diligence.

Next the Court turned its attention to the issue of the discretion of a private investor. Spain argued that a positive net present value is sufficient and that an investor always has a significant margin of discretion. It should be noted that indeed it is true that an investor should undertake a project with positive NPV. But the outcome of the NPV calculation depends on the rate of discount which is used. If the rate of discount is far below the cost of capital, as in this case, then an otherwise loss-making project can show positive results. The Court correctly rejected the plea that the Commission used a faulty methodology in this respect.

With respect to the discretion of a private investor, the Court made a distinction between the estimate of probable project performance, in which a certain margin of discretion exists for the public investor, and the decision whether the performance is sufficient to justify the investment. For the latter decision, the margin of discretion is narrower, since it is possible to compare the transaction in question with other investment opportunities.

Then the Court devoted a large part of its judgment going through and rejecting the many doubts raised by the applicants on the specific figures used by the Commission in the CAPM formula.

The next plea to be considered by the Court was that the Commission wrongly excluded from its calculations revenue from a hotel and other facilities adjacent to the studios. The Court agreed with the applicants. The Court disagreed with the view of the Commission that the hotel and other facilities fell outside the framework of the project. The relevant issue was whether they would generate additional revenue due to the activity of the studios. If they would become more profitable as a result of the operation of the studios, that extra profitability would be taken into account by a private investor. A private investor takes into account all effects of a project. The fact that the hotel and facilities were not strictly within the project of the film studios did not mean that a private investor who owned the hotel would fail to take into account that the film studios would make the hotel more valuable. However, the Court did not annul the Commission decision on these grounds because even after taking into account the extra income from the hotel, the profitability of the studios did not improve much [paragraphs 129-137].

Compatibility

The Court supports the view of the Commission that the aid was not compliant with regional aid rules for the simple reason that CDL had not made at least 25% of the investment from its own resources which had to be free of State aid.

The Court then rejected the arguments advanced by the applicants that the aid could be compatible with cultural aid The project could not be considered as aiming to support heritage conservation. Any type of audiovisual content, as for example, advertisements could be produced by the studios. No evidence was provided purporting to show that films shot at the studios had satisfied any verifiable cultural criteria. All elements thus tended to show that CDL produced films on a purely commercial basis.

Despite the fact that the Commission had approved aid for film production in Spain and Valencia in the past, the aid in this measure was not compatible with the rules concerning aid to cinematography because it did not meet the fourth criterion of compatibility, namely the prohibition of granting aid to specific production activities.

In addition, the aid was not shown to be either necessary, or proportionate, so that it could be exempted on the basis of Article 107(3)(c) or (d). The Commission noted in its decision that there was a highly competitive market in film production. There was no evidence of market failure or shortage of supply of the services in question [paragraph 168].

More importantly, the General Court pointed out that absence of film studios in the Valencia region does not prove market failure [paragraph 168].

Conclusions

The overall lesson that should be drawn from this case is rather simple. If a measure is not designed explicitly at the outset to be free of State aid, it is very difficult afterwards to ensure the compatibility of State aid that is included in that measure by mistake.

A public authority that injects capital in an undertaking [or provides any other kind of finance] must be absolutely sure that the funding can achieve the rate of return or profitability that would satisfy a private investor.

The rate that would ensure that the funding is free of State aid is not the rate that maximises profit or achieves the highest possible return in the universe of investment possibilities, but a rate that covers the cost of capital for that particular investment [i.e. it takes into account the specific risk of that investment].

 

 


[1] The text of the judgment can be accessed at:

http://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=154525&pageIndex=0&doclang=FR&mode=lst&dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=57611

Tags

About

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Related Posts

10. May 2022
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
Risk Finance - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 5

Risk Finance

Risk finance aid in the form of tax relief based on the GBER must be limited to private investors. Introduction Decisions of the European Commission authorising aid for risk finance are very rare. This is the consequence of the success of the Commission to get Member States to use almost exclusively the General Block Exemption Regulation [GBER] for the design […]
21. Dec 2021
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
How to Determine Selectivity - Social Media posts

How to Determine Selectivity

A measure is selective when it excludes undertakings that are equally capable of contributing to the achievement of its objectives. Introduction Since no two undertakings are exactly the same, how can it be determined whether they are in a comparable situation? Differences in their features such as size or the type of technology they use do not necessarily mean that […]
10. Nov 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
What is the Value of Informal Commission Communications? - freighter 315201 1280

What is the Value of Informal Commission Communications?

An official’s statement can be imputed to his authority if it can be reasonably assumed that the official speaks on behalf of the authority. Introduction It is often asked by national officials how much credence they should give to assurances by Commission officials in the absence of a formal Commission decision and what is the legal value of such assurances. […]
27. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
corona virus poster

Identification of Undertakings in Difficulty

A company is in difficulty if, in practice, its accumulated net losses exceed 50% of its subscribed capital, regardless of whether the subscribed capital is formally written down. The classification of a company as being in difficulty is independent of the sector in which it operates and of whether a private investor would be willing to invest in it. Temporary […]
31. Mar 2020
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
How to Make Good the Damage Caused by a Natural Disaster - sergio torres nUw2nIGeGYY unsplash

How to Make Good the Damage Caused by a Natural Disaster

Compensation for costs incurred as a result of a natural disaster is State aid. The compensation must be for damage directly caused by the natural disaster. Introduction State aid to make good the damage caused by an “exceptional occurrence” such as the corona virus covid-19 is compatible with the internal market. The legal basis for exemption is Article 107(2)(b). Of […]
24. Sep 2019
State Aid Uncovered by Phedon Nicolaides
“Invest-NL”: A New Promotional Bank - StateAidHub blogpost39 promotionalbank

“Invest-NL”: A New Promotional Bank

A state-owned promotional or development bank can pursue public policy objectives and also invest on terms which are acceptable to private investors. Introduction During the past decade or so several Member States have established “promotional” or “development” banks for the purpose of investing where the market does not. Private investors may be reluctant to commit their money for a variety […]