Market definition for two-(or multi) sided platforms – demand interdependence and substitution as guiding principles

blackboard whit charts

The past year has led to a lot of discussion on the relation between competition law and (online) platforms and a lot of disagreement on how competition law should apply in such cases as displayed by comments on the major cases of Amex and Google. Unsurprisingly, one of the most contentious aspects of these cases was the market definition. It would appear that performing this task in the case of two-or multi sided platforms has led to quite a few complications. Therefore this post, which summarizes an extensive study on online platforms, seeks provide some clarity and guidance with regard to one of the most important steps in the process of the market definition for platforms. Namely, the question of how many markets need to be defined in the case of two- or multi sided platforms.

Market definition for platforms

Despite the impression that current discussions may give, the concept of platforms is not inherently linked to the digital economy; traditional markets, shopping malls, nightclubs, newspapers and payment cards are all examples of more traditional platforms. These platforms all share the same core principle that determines their success and existence. Namely, these platforms must bring together two (or more) separate customer groups and facilitate the interaction between such groups in return for a fee. The type of interaction facilitated by the platform and the manner in which such service is monetized depends on the value such platform seeks to create for its customers in each case.

In the context of the market definition, the two-sided nature of platforms means that demand-side substitutability could (and should) be assessed with regard to more than one customer group. Accordingly, the market definition process might result in more than one relevant market. Consequently, defining the relevant market for a platform first requires establishing how many markets need to be defined. In the case of two-sided platforms, the choice comes down to defining a single relevant market for the platform of separate relevant markets with regard to the separate customer groups of the platform. The choice between these possibilities has significant consequences for the subsequent test of substitutability and thus the scope of the relevant market. Determining that a single relevant market needs to be defined for the platform means that all the alternatives that will be considered as potential substitutes for the concerned platform must be able meet the demand of all the customer groups of the platform. Consequently, the potential alternatives for the platform must also be platforms. By contrast, if separate relevant markets are defined with regard to the various customer groups of the platform, substitutability is tested separately with regard to each of these groups. Therefore, in this second scenario the potential alternatives for the platform with regard to each of the customer groups of the platform may also include non-platform undertakings.

The difference between the two types of findings cannot be overstated. Defining a single market is likely to result in narrower markets where greater market power and/or more significant anti-competitive effects are likely to be found. By contrast, defining separate markets may lead to opposite findings. Furthermore, evidence of efficiencies in both scenarios will be evaluated differently as dealing with more than a single relevant market will involve looking into out-of-market efficiencies as part of the assessment. Consequently, determining the number of relevant markets that need to be defined in each case is very important for the correct application of (EU) competition law to any type of platform. In the case of online platforms, the matter of market definition entails another layer of complexity as online platforms may often be (or evolve into) multisided markets. Thus, while online platforms share many characteristics with the more traditional offline platforms, getting the answer to the “how many markets” question will be more complex than choosing between one market for the platform or two separate ones for each customer group. Accordingly, before defining the market in the case of an online platform one must first identify the customer groups of the platform that are relevant for the purpose of the case. For example, if LinkedIn were accused of imposing excessive pricing on advertisers, it is not evident that defining the relevant market for recruiters would be needed since there is no demand interdependency between these two customer groups and the LinkedIn platform. However, despite this additional complexity and the differences that may exist among traditional (offline) platforms and online ones, the steps that need to be taken in the process of the market definition are very similar.

Reaching the right conclusion in this matter depends firstly on the correct identification and assessment of the demand interdependency between the various customer groups of the concerned platform in each case.

Understanding demand Inter-dependence

Demand interdependency in the context of platforms refers to the relation between the participation of the platforms’ customer groups on the platform and their mutual demand for the service(s) provided by the platforms. Saying that there is demand interdependence between two-or more customer groups of the platform means, essentially, that the service provided by the platform can only exist when it is provided simultaneously to all such customer groups. In other words, demand interdependency exists when the service provided by the platform to its customer groups depends on having all these groups ‘get on board’. For example open-air markets, similar to online marketplaces, must have both sellers and buyers. Not being able to get one of these groups on board will make such platforms useless for the other customer group(s); a market without buyers or sellers cannot exist offline nor online.

While all platforms will exhibit some degree of demand interdependency, such interdependency will not always be mutual. This (mostly) unilateral demand interdependency relation can been seen in the case of newspapers. The demand of readers for newspapers does not depend on having ads published in them, however, the demand of advertisers for newspapers is evidently dependent on having a large number of readers. Similar conditions also apply to online platforms that use non-search/ display advertising like YouTube. Understanding what kind of demand relations exist among the various customer groups of a platform requires in practice looking at the value the platform wishes to create for its customer groups, the business model behind it and the legal framework which regulates it.

Interdependence and number of relevant markets

When defining the relevant market for a platform with regard to some or all of its customer groups, identifying a unilateral demand interdependency relation between two or more of such groups means that these do no belong to the same relevant market. This is because the demand of one or more of the customer groups could have been met in the absence some of the other customer groups. By contrast, identifying a mutual demand interdependency relation between two or more customer groups means these may be part of a single relevant market. In other words, such customers may consider that the competition of the concerned platform consists solely out of other (online or offline) platforms. The importance of demand interdependency for the purpose of the market definition is also reflected in the distinction between transaction and non-transaction markets for such purpose. Accordingly, when a platform facilitates a transaction between two of more customer groups, the existence of the transaction is an indication that there is a significant degree of mutual demand interdependence between the transacting customer groups.  Such finding in turn increases the chances that the respective customer groups form part of the same relevant market as can be seen in the recent judgment of Ohio v. Amex. However, not every finding of mutual demand interdependence between two or more customer groups, even when it relates to the processing of a transaction, will automatically lead to the conclusion that such customer groups form part of a single relevant market. Markets and online marketplaces both exhibit mutual demand interdependency with regard to their buyers and sellers. However, saying that buyers and sellers are part of the same market in such cases can rarely be said. The reason behind this reality is that buyers will often consider non-platform alternatives, such as groceries stores or online retailers, to be interchangeable with such platforms.

Therefore, in addition to establishing the demand interdependency relation between the platform and its various groups, determining the number of relevant markets that need to be defined is each case requires an elementary substitutability assessment.

Obvious substitution

Once a relation of mutual interdependence between multiple customer groups has been found the next question that needs to be asked is whether the demand of such customers can easily be met by other non-platform undertakings. When the answer to this question is positive, the respective customer groups require the definition of separate relevant markets. For example, the demand of buyers for the services of online marketplaces can usually be met by online retailers.  By contrast the demand for consumers and merchants for the services of a payment platform designed to process transactions such as PayPal, cannot be met by a non-platform undertaking for either consumers or merchants. Therefore, in the case of PayPal a single relevant market could be defined for both customer groups, while defining the relevant market in the case of an online marketplace would require separate relevant markets for its buyers and sellers.  Similar to identifying demand interdependency, establishing the existence of obvious substitution in practice requires looking at the value the platform wishes to create for its customer groups, the business model behind it and the legal framework which regulates it.

Finally, it must be noted that the fact that separate relevant market may be defined in cases concerning platforms, this does not mean that such separate markets can be addressed in isolation for the purpose of the legal analysis in a given case. Two-or multi sided platforms are characterized by network effects which must be taken into account when defining the relevant market, measuring market power and evaluating the anti-competitive effects as well as efficiencies in competition cases. Identifying a demand interdependency relation between various customer groups inherently means that there are indirect network effects between such customer groups which are either unidirectional or mutual depending on the patterns of demand. Consequently, the demand relationship and network effects between the various customer groups of the platform need to be taken into account in each case regardless of the manner in which the relevant market is defined.

Conclusion

The definition of the relevant market in the case of platforms is not an easy process and will likely cause many more debates in ongoing as well as in future cases. Overcoming the expected difficulties in such cases however requires making some adjustments to that manner in which ‘markets’ in the context of competition law are perceived and analyzed. Accordingly, addressing the market definition in the case of platforms adequately firstly requires accepting the existence of two- or multi sided markets as such. Beyond that point an understanding of the demand relationships between the customer groups of platforms and their views on substitution can contribute greatly to reaching the correct findings in each case. Failure to accept and acknowledge such aspects will however likely lead to incorrect findings and prevent competition law from evolving in a future resilient way.

Tags

About

Daniel Mandrescu

Blog editor Assistant Professor EU competition law, Europa Institute, Leiden University >> Daniel's CoRe blog posts >>

Leave a Reply

Related Posts

07. Nov 2024
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
hotel booking platform

Case C-264/23 Booking.com – Ancillary restraints and market definition in the platform economy

The recent judgment of the CJEU in Booking.com represents yet another development in the long series of cases concerning price parity clauses in the platform economy. In Booking.com’s case, the judgment represents the end of the line for its parity clauses. In its greater context of applying EU competition law in the digital economy, the judgment offers new insights into […]
18. Mar 2024
by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, apple app store, the digital markets act

The Apple App Store – A New Kind of Hallmark Case

After almost three years since the Commission sent Apple its statement of objections, which was significantly trimmed down, the Commission reached a finding of abuse for which it imposed a whopping fine of 1.8 billion euros. Alongside this case, Apple was also involved in an almost identical case running parallel in the Netherlands, with similar findings. Meanwhile, during these procedures, […]
16. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
platforms, dma, gatekeepers, digital markets act, apple, google, microsoft, smasung

Rebutting the gatekeeper status – what does it take?

The deadline for appeals on the gatekeeper designation under the DMA is nearing its end.  Since the DMA imposes gatekeepers with demanding obligations, it is only natural that the potential subjects of this regulation will attempt to contest this status. What remains, however, to be clarified is what prospective gatekeepers can put forward as evidence to avoid being designated as […]
07. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
app store, apple, abuse of dominance, platforms, ACM, art. 102 TFEU.

The ACM vs. Apple AppStore – A Second Chance To Get It Right

The Dutch case concerning the Apple App Store appears to make a (welcome) comeback. The case that started in 2019 came to a rather disappointing end in the summer of 2022 when the Dutch competition authority issued a public statement that gave the impression that it was satisfied with Apple’s adjustments to the App Store front in the Netherlands. This […]
26. Oct 2023
by Daniel Mandrescu
airport travel, competition law, platforms, antitrust, EUMR, booking.com, etraveli

Booking / eTraveli: assessing envelopment strategies and mixing up market power thresholds

About a month ago the European Commission announced that it was prohibiting the acquisition of eTraveli by Booking Holdings (Booking.com). The prohibition, which is a rare occurrence in itself, did not attract much attention beyond comments on the ‘ecosystem’ theory of harm which it may have introduced. But this case offers more than that. First, it shows that current practice […]
12. Sep 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Microsoft teams antitrust claim, abuse of dominance, European commission

Microsoft III – Paving The Way To A Tying Trilogy?

This summer the European commission (finally) announced it will start a formal investigation against Microsoft following Slack’s complaint concerning the (abusive) tying or bundling or Teams to the Microsoft and Office 365 suites. Not long after, Microsoft came out with an official statement concerning the changes in its pricing and distribution strategy  of Teams it will introduce in order to […]
31. Aug 2023
by Parsa Tonkaboni
The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight? - 0122 Blog post

The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight?

Introduction On 13 July 2023, the European Court of Justice (‘ECJ’) delivered its highly anticipated ruling in CK Telecoms UK Investments v European Commission (‘CK Telecoms’). The Grand Chamber judgment is significant at the most fundamental level. It clarifies some of the core legal concepts and principles at the very heart of EU merger control. The five crucial issues the […]
18. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, refusal to supply, Lithuanian railways, bronner, essential facility, art. 102 TFEU

Case C-42/21P Lithuanian Railways – another clarification on the Bronner case law and the non-exhaustive character of art. 102 TFEU

The recent case of Lithuanian Railways provides yet another clarification on the scope of application of the Bronner case law. The Judgement of the CJEU reconfirms exceptional character of the Bronner case law and the type of situations it is intended to apply to. By doing so the CJEU potentially helps prevent future disputes of a similar  nature in the […]
03. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
facebook, competition law, abuse of dominance, art. 102 TFEU, multisided platforms, dominant position, tying and bundling, unfair trading conditions, competition economics, european commission,

On-platform Tying or Another Case of Leveraging- A Discussion on Facebook Marketplace

Just before 2022 ended the Commission sent a statement of objections to Meta regarding the potential abusive behaviour of Facebook. According to the statement of objections, Facebook may be engaging in (i) abusive tying practices with regard to Facebook Marketplace as users (i.e. consumers) that log into Facebook and are automatically also offered access to the Facebook Marketplace, without the […]
07. Dec 2022
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
market definition notice, relevant market, market power, market analysis, notice update, digital platforms, multisided markets, multisided platforms, online platforms, SSNIP test, SSNDQ test, Google android, Google shopping, merger control, abuse of dominance

The draft notice on market definition and multisided (digital) platforms – avoiding rather than resolving some of the main challenges

Approximately a month ago the Commission published its draft notice on the definition of the relevant market. The new notice is supposed to replace the old one that dates back to 1997 and thereby bring the entire process up to date with today’s new challenges, particularly in the context of digital markets. A first read of this long awaited document […]

Subscribe to our newsletter for updates on legal developments, upcoming conferences, workshops, and publications in your areas of interest.

Newsletter: Subscribe now