Epic v Apple (3): two perspectives on app stores’ 30% commission fee

app stores, App Store, Google Play, 30%, commission fee, Epic, Spotify, Netflix, excessive pricing, tying, bundling, exploitation, exclusion, European Commission

In a first blog post in this Epic v Apple series, we introduced the high-stakes dispute and the context necessary for understanding it. A second blog post discussed market power in app distribution and access to Apple and Google’s ecosystems under refusal to supply/foreclosure theories of harm. This third post zooms in on the most contentious feature of Apple’s App Store and Google’s Play Store: the 30% commission fee they charge on (in-)app purchases.

Introduction

The intricacies of the App Store’s In-App Purchase system (IAP) were already set out earlier. The policy of Google Play Billing (GPB)—IAP’s counterpart in the Play Store—is similar. Until recently, however, Google did not enforce its billing policy as strictly as Apple, which meant that a lot of apps (including Netflix and Spotify) could use their own billing system rather than GPB, thus bypassing the 30% fee. However, on September 28, Google provided ‘clarity of billing policies’, stressing that all developers offering in-app purchases of digital goods (say, a video or music subscription) must use GPB.

The consequences of this move are not yet clear. Just like within the App Store, Netflix and Spotify may simply disable in-app billing. This move has the benefit of denying Google Play its cut, but also makes it impossible for consumers to subscribe within the app. Given that Netflix and Spotify qualify as so-called ‘reader’ apps, they have the ‘luxury’ of being able to disable IAP/GPB: user can still subscribe through their website and then log in on the app.

Other developers, such as Fortnite creator Epic, are not allowed to bypass the app stores’ billing systems in this way. In the past, Epic has therefore experimented with completely pulling its app from the Play Store and having users ‘side-load’ it instead (i.e. download it directly from the web). However, the Dutch competition authority, which examined this experiment in a report on app stores, came to sobering conclusions: Epic lost an estimated 41% of Fortnite downloads, seemingly losing users to competing game PUBG. Epic could not have even attempted such an experiment within Apple’s iOS, because side-loading is impossible within that ecosystem.

The 30% commission fee is thus here to stay—and is only becoming more unavoidable. On top of Google tightening its policies, Apple rejected an attempt by Facebook to simply inform users of App Store fees. Of course, these fees are at the heart of a number of antitrust cases, including not only Epic’s suit against Apple and Google, but also the investigations of the App Store by the European Commission (spurred by Spotify) and the Dutch competition authority.

With these cases in mind, it is important to understand that there are two ways of looking at the 30% commission fee. One the one hand, you could focus on the (high) level of the commission fee—the perspective of exploitation. One the other hand, you could examine how the commission fee is sustained, i.e. by not allowing others to provide app store payment processing—the perspective of exclusion. Let’s dive deeper into those two perspectives, focusing on the App Store and EU competition law.

Exploitation: is 30% excessive?

Article 102(a) TFEU prohibits ‘imposing unfair … prices or other unfair trading conditions’. Could Apple’s 30% commission fees constitute such an unfair price? According to the ECJ, a price is unfair—or excessive—when ‘it has no reasonable relation to the economic value of the product supplied’ (see e.g. United Brands and AKKA/LAA). This formula has been operationalized through a two-pronged test: first, one has to determine whether the difference between the costs actually incurred and the price actually charged—i.e. the profit margin—is excessive; second, if the profit margin is excessive, it must be established whether the price is unfair in itself or in comparison to the prices of competitors.

The App Store’s profit margin is undoubtedly high: while the number is not public, some analysts put it at 90%. But is the 30% fee comparatively high? This depends, of course, on the chosen point of comparison. Play Store fees are also set at 30%, but this point of comparison is unhelpful given that Google also enjoys market power. And even app stores without market power model their fees on market leader Apple.

Perhaps pc game stores offer a more useful point of comparison. Here too the incumbent (Steam) charges a 30% fee for distribution. However, this fee is meaningfully being challenged by Epic, which set up its own store charging only a 12% fee. As explained earlier, Epic’s complaint seeks to achieve exactly this: the possibility to set up its own app store (with lower commission fees) within Apple’s ecosystem.

Finally, Geradin and Katsifis argue that Apple is not offering distribution services, but just payment processing and related services. One would then have to compare Apple’s 30% fee with those of PayPal, Stripe and like, which hover around 3% (often combined with a small fixed fee). While Apple’s price does look excessive from this perspective (it’s ten times higher), it must be acknowledged that the App Store’s distribution service exceeds simple payment processing.

However, this quantitative method may not be the right one. Apple has stated that ‘84% of apps obtained through the App Store share no revenue with Apple’ (these include, e.g., ‘free’ apps that are monetized through advertising). This means that a small minority of developers is subsidizing the great majority of developers: they overpay while others benefit freely from the App Store. Perhaps the unfairness of the fees is rather found in this imbalance, even though such an analysis does not fit naturally with the established excessive pricing test.

Exclusion: is app distribution tied to payment processing?

Instead of focusing on the level of fees, one could examine how they are sustained, namely through a form of tying (prohibited by Article 102(d) TFEU). There is no way to distribute apps within iOS other than through the App Store, which may be viewed as a tie between the operating system (tying product) and the app store (tied product). And there is no other way to pay for apps in the App Store than through IAP, which may be considered a tie between the app store (tying product) and payment processing (tied product).

In order for tying to be abusive, the products in question must be separate products, customers must be unable to get the tying product with the tied product (coercion), and there must be foreclosure in either the tying or the tied market (see e.g. Hilti and Microsoft).

To test whether separate products are being tied together, the EC generally examines whether there is distinct demand for the tied product. When it comes to app stores, this does seem to be the case: app developers have been complaining about the lack of alternatives to the App Store for years (and Epic seems ready to supply one), while consumers go as far as jailbreaking their iPhone to access other app stores. IAP also seems to be a distinct product: Apple only introduced this feature after the App Store, and payment providers already take care of billing of App Store transactions that are not obliged to use IAP.

When it comes to coercion, Apple prevents—both technically and contractually—that iOS users use any other app store than the App Store (of course, it’s impossible for alternative app stores to exist within iOS in the first place). And when selling digital goods, developers have no choice but to use IAP (unless they qualify as reader apps).

Insofar as there is foreclosure in this case, it is situated in the markets of the tied products, i.e. app stores and app payment processing. Entry into those markets is being restricted if not made impossible. All of this is significantly different in Google’s Android OS, which does allow for competing app stores (such as Amazon’s), although they have to be side-loaded.

Importantly, however, one has to consider whether this potential form of abuse can be justified. Apple prides itself on the user-friendliness and security of its ecosystem, which is attained—at least in part—by excluding other app stores from iOS. We must thus ask whether this restriction is proportionate to the benefits achieved by it. Is Android, which is policed less restrictively (e.g. by flagging, hiding and suspending app stores considered unsafe) so much less secure?

Processing (in-)app purchases exclusively through IAP can also reasonably be explained by a concern for free-riding: if every app developer could use alternative payment processors, Apple would be unable to fund its continuous investment in the App Store. At the very least, it would have to start actually competing with those other payment processors, which would certainly lead to a lower fee. Again, the question is whether this restriction is proportionate to its goal.

Conclusion

A consensus is building that the fees charged by app stores are too high. While app developers have long complained, they are now joined by prominent venture capitalists (e.g. Bill Gurley), tech commentators (e.g. Ben Thompson and Ben Evans) and other big tech companies (Microsoft and Facebook). The hardest part may be figuring out a suitable remedy.

An excessive pricing perspective calls for simply lowering App Store fees. By contrast, a tying perspective would result in the unbundling of the App Store and payment processing. In that case, however, Apple would be providing (even more) developers with free distribution. Would it then start charging a distribution fee separate from payment processing? Or would it derive its profit from a more competitive commission fee? (Of course, Apple also profits indirectly from the App Store and the apps in it, through the sale of iPhones.)

Some argue for a differentiated solution. After all, the digital goods sold by Fortnite (‘skins’) are produced at zero marginal cost—is a 30% fee then really problematic? By contrast, firms like Spotify have high marginal costs—for them, the 30% fee can mean the difference between profitability and losses. However, drawing a clear dividing line between these two categories of app is no easy feat.

Finally, as more often, the solution may not be a legal one, but rather a technological one. When Apple didn’t allow the cloud gaming services of Microsoft (xCloud) and Google (Stadia) in the App Store, Amazon launched its cloud gaming service as a web app. Microsoft plans to do the same. Relying on the web rather than a native app has drawbacks, but innovation in/competition from this sphere may prompt change.

Tags

About

Friso Bostoen

Blog Editor

Assistant Professor of Competition Law and Digital Regulation, Tilburg University

Friso Bostoen is an assistant professor of competition law and digital regulation at Tilburg University. Previously, he was a Max Weber Fellow at the European University Institute. He holds degrees from KU Leuven (PhD, LLM) and Harvard University (LLM). Friso’s research focuses on antitrust enforcement in digital markets. His work has resulted in numerous international publications, presentations, and awards (including the AdC Competition Policy Award 2019 and the Concurrences PhD Award 2022). In addition, Friso edits the CoRe Blog and hosts the Monopoly Attack podcast.

>> Friso’s CoRe Blog posts >>

Related Posts

18. Mar 2024
by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, apple app store, the digital markets act

The Apple App Store – A New Kind of Hallmark Case

After almost three years since the Commission sent Apple its statement of objections, which was significantly trimmed down, the Commission reached a finding of abuse for which it imposed a whopping fine of 1.8 billion euros. Alongside this case, Apple was also involved in an almost identical case running parallel in the Netherlands, with similar findings. Meanwhile, during these procedures, […]
07. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
app store, apple, abuse of dominance, platforms, ACM, art. 102 TFEU.

The ACM vs. Apple AppStore – A Second Chance To Get It Right

The Dutch case concerning the Apple App Store appears to make a (welcome) comeback. The case that started in 2019 came to a rather disappointing end in the summer of 2022 when the Dutch competition authority issued a public statement that gave the impression that it was satisfied with Apple’s adjustments to the App Store front in the Netherlands. This […]
26. Oct 2023
by Daniel Mandrescu
airport travel, competition law, platforms, antitrust, EUMR, booking.com, etraveli

Booking / eTraveli: assessing envelopment strategies and mixing up market power thresholds

About a month ago the European Commission announced that it was prohibiting the acquisition of eTraveli by Booking Holdings (Booking.com). The prohibition, which is a rare occurrence in itself, did not attract much attention beyond comments on the ‘ecosystem’ theory of harm which it may have introduced. But this case offers more than that. First, it shows that current practice […]
12. Sep 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Microsoft teams antitrust claim, abuse of dominance, European commission

Microsoft III – Paving The Way To A Tying Trilogy?

This summer the European commission (finally) announced it will start a formal investigation against Microsoft following Slack’s complaint concerning the (abusive) tying or bundling or Teams to the Microsoft and Office 365 suites. Not long after, Microsoft came out with an official statement concerning the changes in its pricing and distribution strategy  of Teams it will introduce in order to […]
31. Aug 2023
by Parsa Tonkaboni
The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight? - 0122 Blog post

The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight?

Introduction On 13 July 2023, the European Court of Justice (‘ECJ’) delivered its highly anticipated ruling in CK Telecoms UK Investments v European Commission (‘CK Telecoms’). The Grand Chamber judgment is significant at the most fundamental level. It clarifies some of the core legal concepts and principles at the very heart of EU merger control. The five crucial issues the […]
08. Mar 2023
Features by Friso Bostoen
Requiem for an objection: the Commission drops half of its App Store case - zhiyue 7DOU5NlNIcE unsplash

Requiem for an objection: the Commission drops half of its App Store case

On 28 February 2023, the European Commission (EC) sent Apple a new Statement of Objections (SO) ‘clarifying its concerns over App Store rules for music streaming providers’. Rather than a clarification, or an expansion of the previous SO, the new SO dropped one of the two objections—an unusual move, especially at this stage of the proceedings. When a startup shuts […]
18. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, refusal to supply, Lithuanian railways, bronner, essential facility, art. 102 TFEU

Case C-42/21P Lithuanian Railways – another clarification on the Bronner case law and the non-exhaustive character of art. 102 TFEU

The recent case of Lithuanian Railways provides yet another clarification on the scope of application of the Bronner case law. The Judgement of the CJEU reconfirms exceptional character of the Bronner case law and the type of situations it is intended to apply to. By doing so the CJEU potentially helps prevent future disputes of a similar  nature in the […]
03. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
facebook, competition law, abuse of dominance, art. 102 TFEU, multisided platforms, dominant position, tying and bundling, unfair trading conditions, competition economics, european commission,

On-platform Tying or Another Case of Leveraging- A Discussion on Facebook Marketplace

Just before 2022 ended the Commission sent a statement of objections to Meta regarding the potential abusive behaviour of Facebook. According to the statement of objections, Facebook may be engaging in (i) abusive tying practices with regard to Facebook Marketplace as users (i.e. consumers) that log into Facebook and are automatically also offered access to the Facebook Marketplace, without the […]
15. Nov 2022
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
abuse of dominance, competition law, art. 102 TFEU, railways, regulation, DMA, excessive pricing, unfair pricing, private enforcement, stand alone claims

Case C-721/20 – DB Station & Service – Can secondary legislation limit the private enforcement of art. 102 TFEU?

Last month the CJEU delivered an interesting ruling on the scope of application of art. 102 TFEU when dealing with excessive or unfair prices in the railway sector. A first reading of the final conclusion of the CJEU would give the impression that the scope of application of art. 102 TFEU is being unduly restricted with this case by making […]
01. Apr 2022
Features by Friso Bostoen
The French judgment on Google’s Play Store: a shift towards platform exploitation? - The French judgment on

The French judgment on Google’s Play Store: a shift towards platform exploitation?

On 28 March 2022, the Commercial Court of Paris fined Google €2 million for the imbalanced terms and conditions of its Play Store. While the fine is minimal, Google is also obliged to adapt those T&Cs, including the 30% fee—a much more far-reaching implication. Except for some news articles, the French judgment did not receive a lot of attention (which […]

Subscribe to our newsletter for updates on legal developments, upcoming conferences, workshops, and publications in your areas of interest.

Newsletter: Subscribe now