Online platforms and refusal to deal – Unlockd vs. Google – a seminal case in the making?

Online platforms and refusal to deal - Unlockd vs. Google - a seminal case in the making? - brooke lark W1B2LpQOBxA unsplash

The recent standoff between advertisement application developer Unlockd and Google, concerning the removal of Unlockd from the Google Play Store and AdMob marketplace, may turn out to be one of the most important competition law cases of the year. This case, which will likely require a competition law review of Google’s terms and conditions for these platforms, provides the opportunity to assess the meaning of exclusionary practices in the context of two- sided (online) platforms.

Background to the case

The Unlockd advertisement apps have gained significant popularity in the past few years due to Unlocked’s different approach to mobile advertising. The idea behind the Unlockd apps is rather simple: consumers that install the apps agree to consume or be exposed to content, such as advertising, when they unlock their phone in return for rewards like a reduction on their monthly phone bill or store credits. Accordingly the all-too-often used catch phrase – consumers are paying with their attention when it comes to the digital economy – appears to have turned into- consumers are being paid for their attention- in the case of Unlockd .

Unfortunately for Unlockd, however, Google plans to remove Unlockd’s apps from the Play Store and AdMob advertising marketplace due to an alleged violation of the terms and conditions of these platforms. Removing Unlocked’s apps, which only work on Android OS, from the Play Store would evidently have a significant detrimental effect on the viability of the company. Android phone users will still be able to download Unlockd’s apps from other sources. Nevertheless, the Google Play Store is evidently a principal outlet for any Android app. Therefore, Unlockd launched an injunction procedure in the UK requesting to suspend its removal from the Google platforms. In this procedure Unlocked claimed the plan of Google to remove its apps from the Play Store and AdMob platforms constitutes anti-competitive practice. In light of such claims of anti-competitive behavior, Unlockd requested the UK courts to prohibit Google to undertake any steps concerning the removal of Unlockd’s apps until a thorough competition law assessment has been conducted. On Wednesday,9th of May,  this interim injunction was granted by Judge Peter Roth for Unlockd’s apps made for the UK market.

Although there is very limited information on the case beyond the statements made by both Google and Unlockd in the press, the circumstances alone are sufficient to understand that this case can be a meaningful one. The legal analysis of Google’s plans will inevitably require addressing the matter of dominance and governance of two-sided platforms under the scope of Art. 102 TFEU, and possibly even include a discussion on the essential facility doctrine in the digital economy.

Online platforms and dominance

Due to the fact that the claims in this case concern the unilateral behavior of Google, establishing the existence of any anti-competitive behavior of its behalf essentially entails finding an abuse of dominance. Finding such an abuse firstly requires assessing whether the concerned undertaking, in this case Google, is dominant. Establishing dominance requires defining the relevant market as a prerequisite to reaching such final conclusion (Case T-62/98 Volkswagen v Commission). In this particular case the dominance of Google, and therefore the market definition, will concern the Google Play Store which constitutes a two-sided online platform.

Defining the relevant market in this case would normally first require establishing how many markets need to be defined (on this matter see also the Dutch Funda case). In the case of two-sided (online) platforms, the choice boils down to defining a single relevant market for the platform or two separate relevant markets with regard to the customer groups participating on the platform, in this case consumers and app developers. While making that choice entails many complexities and has been the subject of extensive debate, the case of the Google Play Store is rather straightforward. The relevant market in such situation should a single one including both sides of the platform (consumers and app developers). Although apps can be distributed and downloaded via non-platform outlets, namely the developers’ own website, such an option is not likely to be considered interchangeable with the Google Play Store from the perspective of both consumers and developers. Consequently the relevant market should consist of all other platforms where consumers can download android apps (and developers can upload them) such as other app stores, which offer their services to the EU market (or at least the UK market). Although a proper analysis remains to be performed, it is quite likely that Google would possess a dominant position on such market. Having a dominant position on the market creates special obligations for the concerned undertakings. However, it is not prohibited as such under competition law. It is only the abuse of such a position which requires intervention. In this case, assessing whether an abuse occurred involves an interesting discussion with regard to the governance of (dominant) online platforms.

(Online) Platform Governance and Exclusion

Generally speaking, all two-multisided (online) platforms face the same chicken-and-egg problem, namely, they must convince one user group to join the platform before members of the other group(s) necessary for the interaction facilitated by the platform also join. The belief is that once this initial launch phase is successful, scalability and critical mass will be quickly achieved due to indirect network effects thus making the platform viable. Accordingly, various launching strategies have been adopted by online platforms based on the nature of the value they seek to create and monetize. In the life cycle of an online platform it is not only the launching strategy is crucial to its success but also its governance. The governance constitutes the rules which determine how platform participation should take places, in other words the do’s and don’ts for the platforms’ user groups. The governance helps the platform eradicate undesired activity and thus determines to a great extent the quality and value of the service it provides its user groups. If the platform’s governance is not on point, the indirect network effects that helped the platform scale up may work in reverse and be the cause of its fall rather than rise. With this in mind, it is rather evident that at some point in time every online platform is bound to exclude/remove or refuse the access of certain participants on the platform based on its governance considerations. When the platform has a dominant position, however, such exclusion may raise a few doubts with regard to its compatibility with competition law.

This is roughly the situation in the case on Unlockd and Google, where Google seeks to remove Unlockd’s app from the Play Store due to an alleged violation of its terms and conditions (i.e. based on the governance of Google with regard to the Play Store). In this situation the question is not only whether Unlockd was indeed in breach of such terms and conditions, but also whether the exclusion of Unlockd based on such breach is abusive in this particular case. If no breach of terms occurred then the exclusion of Unlockd would be unlawful (not only from a competition law perspective). However, if a breach were to be established, the situation becomes a bit more complex depending on the relationship between Unlockd’s business model and that of the Google Play Store. Accordingly, if the presence of Unlockd on the Google Play Store undermines growth of the Play Store and/or reduces the quality of the Play Store in the eyes of its other participants, exclusion from the Play Store may be justified. The removal of the Amazon App Store, Disconnect and Grooveshark applications from the Play Store are examples of such situations. In these cases the removed applications interfered with the success of the Play Store itself. The Amazon app allowed for the purchasing of other apps through it, thus diverting users from the Play Store to the Amazon app; the Disconnect app allowed users to block advertisements and tracking activities by other applications, thus interfering with the business models of most apps offered in the Play Store; and Grooveshark was facing IP rights/ piracy claims. Therefore, excluding such apps from the platform seemed to make sense in these previous cases. Although dominant undertakings may have a special responsibility not to interfere with competition, this does not go as far as obliging such undertakings to consciously undermine their own success. However, if the breach of terms and conditions is one that is not capable of interfering with the business model of the platform, removal from the platform (which has a dominant position) may prove to be abusive. This is because such removal will inevitably have an impact on competition but cannot be considered to have the aim of protecting legitimate business practices. Consequently, under such circumstances questions concerning refusal to deal and the essential facility doctrine may become relevant.

Refusal to deal with a pinch of tying

Refusal to deal cases always entail striking a balance between the freedom of each undertaking to conduct its business according to its preferences and the promotion of competition. There is no doubt that obliging undertakings, even dominant ones, to deal with rivals or customers against their will is a scenario which needs to be avoided as much as possible. Consequently, the case law regulating this matter introduced a very strict legal test for imposing such an obligation on a dominant undertaking. The legal test, often referred to as the ‘essential facility test’, requires dominant undertaking to deal with rivals when (i) a refusal is only abusive when it concerns input that is indispensable for carrying out business on a related market; (ii) the refusal is capable of eliminating effective competition; (iii) the refusal prevents the emergence of new products for which there is potential consumer demand; and (iv) the refusal is not objectively justified.

The difficulty with this test lies primarily with the indispensability criterion, which is applied very strictly in current case law. In order for a facility, such as the Google Play Store, to be indispensable there must not be other available alternatives and reproducing such a facility cannot be done in an economically viable manner from an objective point of view [See CJEU and AG Jacobs in Bronner ]. In the case of the Play Store this criterion appears impossible to meet since there are already other alternative Android app stores. The fact that the Google Play Store may be more preferred by users is not sufficient to change this. While normally the discussion on the concept of indispensability and the application of the essential facility doctrine would simply end here, the case of Google has another layer of complexity. This complexity relates to the fact that the Google Play Store is by default pre-installed on most, if not all, android devices sold in the EU. This practice is already the subject of other competition law investigations but might also be relevant in this case. Accordingly, the question is whether this pre-installation, which is not necessarily a reflection of consumer choice but rather the lack of it, can make the google Play Store de facto indispensable. Other app stores can of course be installed later by consumers but it is evident that such pre-installation may reduce multi-homing tendencies, thus diminishing the substitution potential of alternative app stores for both users and developers. Finally, it is important to note that although the thought experiment in this post is focused on the Google Play Store, similar considerations may equally apply to the removal of Unlockd from the AdMob advertisement marketplace.

Conclusion

Although there is very little information on the facts of this case at this moment this battle between Google and Unlockd is certainly worth following (so expect more posts). Whether the discussion in practice will go as far as discussed here remains to be seen. The case can just as easily turn out to be a case of abusive discrimination in the way the terms and conditions of the Google Play store are applied, or no abuse at all. However, at some point in time the matters discussed here will have to be addressed to some extent with regard to platform refusals or removals so why not get a head start with the most interesting scenario?

Tags

About

Daniel Mandrescu

Blog editor Assistant Professor EU competition law, Europa Institute, Leiden University >> Daniel's CoRe blog posts >>

Leave a Reply

Related Posts

07. Nov 2024
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
hotel booking platform

Case C-264/23 Booking.com – Ancillary restraints and market definition in the platform economy

The recent judgment of the CJEU in Booking.com represents yet another development in the long series of cases concerning price parity clauses in the platform economy. In Booking.com’s case, the judgment represents the end of the line for its parity clauses. In its greater context of applying EU competition law in the digital economy, the judgment offers new insights into […]
18. Mar 2024
by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, apple app store, the digital markets act

The Apple App Store – A New Kind of Hallmark Case

After almost three years since the Commission sent Apple its statement of objections, which was significantly trimmed down, the Commission reached a finding of abuse for which it imposed a whopping fine of 1.8 billion euros. Alongside this case, Apple was also involved in an almost identical case running parallel in the Netherlands, with similar findings. Meanwhile, during these procedures, […]
16. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
platforms, dma, gatekeepers, digital markets act, apple, google, microsoft, smasung

Rebutting the gatekeeper status – what does it take?

The deadline for appeals on the gatekeeper designation under the DMA is nearing its end.  Since the DMA imposes gatekeepers with demanding obligations, it is only natural that the potential subjects of this regulation will attempt to contest this status. What remains, however, to be clarified is what prospective gatekeepers can put forward as evidence to avoid being designated as […]
07. Nov 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
app store, apple, abuse of dominance, platforms, ACM, art. 102 TFEU.

The ACM vs. Apple AppStore – A Second Chance To Get It Right

The Dutch case concerning the Apple App Store appears to make a (welcome) comeback. The case that started in 2019 came to a rather disappointing end in the summer of 2022 when the Dutch competition authority issued a public statement that gave the impression that it was satisfied with Apple’s adjustments to the App Store front in the Netherlands. This […]
26. Oct 2023
by Daniel Mandrescu
airport travel, competition law, platforms, antitrust, EUMR, booking.com, etraveli

Booking / eTraveli: assessing envelopment strategies and mixing up market power thresholds

About a month ago the European Commission announced that it was prohibiting the acquisition of eTraveli by Booking Holdings (Booking.com). The prohibition, which is a rare occurrence in itself, did not attract much attention beyond comments on the ‘ecosystem’ theory of harm which it may have introduced. But this case offers more than that. First, it shows that current practice […]
12. Sep 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
Microsoft teams antitrust claim, abuse of dominance, European commission

Microsoft III – Paving The Way To A Tying Trilogy?

This summer the European commission (finally) announced it will start a formal investigation against Microsoft following Slack’s complaint concerning the (abusive) tying or bundling or Teams to the Microsoft and Office 365 suites. Not long after, Microsoft came out with an official statement concerning the changes in its pricing and distribution strategy  of Teams it will introduce in order to […]
31. Aug 2023
by Parsa Tonkaboni
The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight? - 0122 Blog post

The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight?

Introduction On 13 July 2023, the European Court of Justice (‘ECJ’) delivered its highly anticipated ruling in CK Telecoms UK Investments v European Commission (‘CK Telecoms’). The Grand Chamber judgment is significant at the most fundamental level. It clarifies some of the core legal concepts and principles at the very heart of EU merger control. The five crucial issues the […]
18. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, refusal to supply, Lithuanian railways, bronner, essential facility, art. 102 TFEU

Case C-42/21P Lithuanian Railways – another clarification on the Bronner case law and the non-exhaustive character of art. 102 TFEU

The recent case of Lithuanian Railways provides yet another clarification on the scope of application of the Bronner case law. The Judgement of the CJEU reconfirms exceptional character of the Bronner case law and the type of situations it is intended to apply to. By doing so the CJEU potentially helps prevent future disputes of a similar  nature in the […]
03. Jan 2023
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
facebook, competition law, abuse of dominance, art. 102 TFEU, multisided platforms, dominant position, tying and bundling, unfair trading conditions, competition economics, european commission,

On-platform Tying or Another Case of Leveraging- A Discussion on Facebook Marketplace

Just before 2022 ended the Commission sent a statement of objections to Meta regarding the potential abusive behaviour of Facebook. According to the statement of objections, Facebook may be engaging in (i) abusive tying practices with regard to Facebook Marketplace as users (i.e. consumers) that log into Facebook and are automatically also offered access to the Facebook Marketplace, without the […]
07. Dec 2022
Features by Daniel Mandrescu
market definition notice, relevant market, market power, market analysis, notice update, digital platforms, multisided markets, multisided platforms, online platforms, SSNIP test, SSNDQ test, Google android, Google shopping, merger control, abuse of dominance

The draft notice on market definition and multisided (digital) platforms – avoiding rather than resolving some of the main challenges

Approximately a month ago the Commission published its draft notice on the definition of the relevant market. The new notice is supposed to replace the old one that dates back to 1997 and thereby bring the entire process up to date with today’s new challenges, particularly in the context of digital markets. A first read of this long awaited document […]

Subscribe to our newsletter for updates on legal developments, upcoming conferences, workshops, and publications in your areas of interest.

Newsletter: Subscribe now