The Commission’s Amazon probe: overcoming the antitrust paradox

The Commission’s Amazon probe: overcoming the antitrust paradox - P037742 506967 640x400 1

In a press conference on September 19th, EU Commissioner for Competition Margrethe Vestager announced a preliminary investigation into Amazon. At the heart of the potentially abusive conduct is Amazon’s ‘dual role’. One the one hand, Amazon offers a marketplace for third-party sellers to offer their products to consumers. On the other hand, Amazon offers its own products through its marketplace. The Commission’s allegation appears to be that Amazon uses the data it gathers on third-party transactions to boost the sales of its own products. In this blog post, I examine where the investigation is coming from, where it may be headed, and which related developments can influence it.

Where is the investigation coming from?

As to the origin of the investigation, Vestager noted that the conduct in question was first observed in the Commission’s E-Commerce Sector Inquiry. Indeed, in a staff working document accompanying last year’s final report on the inquiry, the Commission noted (para 651):

Marketplace operators sometimes act as an online retailer on their platform in direct competition with third party sellers. Competitively sensitive data provided by third party sellers to marketplaces or generated on marketplaces in relation to third-party transactions (e.g. bestsellers, transactional prices and pricing plans, inventory levels, supplier data) could – absent any safeguards in place – be used in order to boost the retail activities of the marketplace operators at the expense of third party sellers.

The Commission already concluded at the time that such behavior could potentially raise competition concerns.

However, there is an additional reason for investigating Amazon’s conduct. According to Vestager, ‘it’s also what a lot of people are talking about’. That is no overstatement. The last two years have seen a series of news articles raising concerns about Amazon’s dual role on its platform (see e.g. BloombergGuardian x2Wall Street JournalNew York Times and Buzzfeed). Those articles have two recurring themes.

Firstly, they use the example of a well-reviewed laptop stand sold on Amazon Marketplace by the company Rain. Amazon allegedly copied the laptop stand, and then started selling it at a lower price while also giving it more favourable placement in its product listing. Secondly—and more fundamentally—they cite Lina Khan, Director of Legal Policy at the Open Markets Institute.

Lina Khan has been shaking up antitrust circles since the publication of her article ‘Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox’ in Yale Law Journal last year. In a nearly 100-page article discussing (US) antitrust law’s failure to capture anti-competitive conduct by Amazon, she devotes four pages to Amazon’s exploitation of the data collected on its marketplace (pp. 780-783).

In those pages, Khan diagnoses the problem the Commission appears to be looking at. Amazon is vertically integrated in the sense that it offers not only the infrastructure for the commerce of third parties, but also offer its own products through this infrastructure. It uses the vast sales data it gathers on its platform to guide which product spaces to enter, and then pushes out competitors by undercutting them on price and/or giving its own items featured placement.

The question, however, is whether this diagnosis is correct, and if so, what the remedy is.

Where is the investigation headed?

Vestager stressed that the investigation is in its ‘very early days’. She acknowledges that Amazon’s use of data can be perfectly legitimate when used to improve its service to third-party sellers. However, she is concerned that Amazon uses also uses this data for its calculations as to ‘what is the new big thing, what is it that people want, what kind of offers do they like to receive, what makes them buy things’. To find out, the Commission has sent questionnaires to third-party sellers on Amazon Marketplace (available in German here).

Dominance

This shapes up to be an abuse of dominance case under Article 102 TFEU, so the Commission will have to define Amazon’s market and establish its dominant position on it. As Amazon Marketplace operates a two-sided market, connecting consumers with sellers (the ‘sides’ of the market), market definition is not a straightforward exercise: do we define separate markets for each side, or one intermediation market? (See last week’s blog post on the issue.)

When looking at Amazon’s price parity clauses in 2013, the Bundeskartellamt chose the latter option, defining the market as that for ‘B2C online platform services for the sale of a general product range’, excluding auction platforms and price comparison engines. There are, however, no publicly available sources on Amazon’s share in this market.

Theory of harm

If the Commission finds dominance, it will need a credible theory of harm, which is—again—no easy feat. It may draw inspiration from its Google Search decision, where it found that Google used its search engine to favour its own comparison shopping services over those of third parties. As Amazon is also said to use its platform to favour its products in the downstream market, its conduct is similar. The Commission’s argument then goes that excluding third parties reduces both innovation and consumer choice. Amazon will undoubtedly counter that its conduct lowers prices.

However, the Commission may want to look further back for precedent (especially as its Google Search decision is being challenged before the General Court). Exclusion of downstream competitors by vertically integrated undertakings—in particular telecom operators—was at the heart of the margin squeeze cases that ran throughout the 2000s. Yours truly has argued this assessment framework may also be applicable to exclusionary conduct of online platforms.

Supporting data

In any case, the Commission has some data to work with. Hagiu and Wright have empirically tested Amazon’s process of vertical integration, noting that ‘once Amazon reaches information parity with its sellers, it switches [from the marketplace] to the reseller mode in order to exploit its scale advantage.’ They find that Amazon particularly starts selling short-tail products. Zhu and Liu confirm that Amazon targets products with greater demand, and add that higher prices and lower shipping costs also guide the process.

Zhu and Liu have also empirically analyzed the effects of Amazon’s entry into third-party sellers’ product spaces. They find that ‘Amazon’s entry discourages affected third-party sellers from subsequently pursuing growth on the platform, [but] increases product demand and reduces shipping costs for consumers.’ Other research finds that Amazon’s algorithmic steering practices may lead consumers to pay more, although this is mostly limited to consumers who do not subscribe to Amazon’s Prime service.

While helpful, these results are far from conclusive. Given that Amazon’s conduct will be assessed as a ‘by effect’ rather than an ‘by object’ abuse, the Commission will have to demonstrate its anti-competitive consequences. Moreover, it will have to come up with an effective remedy. A behavioural separation between Amazon’s marketplace and retail activities is the most obvious solution. However, given the criticism on such remedy in the Google Search case, some might be more drawn to a structural separation.

Related developments

The Commission’s probe targets one platform-to-business relation. However, the Commission has recently also adopted a proposal to regulate such relations generally. As explained in a previous blog post, the regulation would oblige platforms to be transparent regarding any differentiated treatment between the platform and its business users when it comes to access to data and rankings of search results.

Finally, the Commission does not appear to be the only authority concerned about Amazon’s practices. MLex reported that Amazon’s dual role has also caught the eye of German antitrust enforcers. Finally, Capitol Forum—a US news service focused on antitrust—has also investigated how Amazon favours its own products, and concluded that this conduct risks antitrust enforcement by the Trump administration.

Tags

Über

Friso Bostoen

Blog Editor

Assistant Professor of Competition Law and Digital Regulation, Tilburg University

Friso Bostoen is an assistant professor of competition law and digital regulation at Tilburg University. Previously, he was a Max Weber Fellow at the European University Institute. He holds degrees from KU Leuven (PhD, LLM) and Harvard University (LLM). Friso’s research focuses on antitrust enforcement in digital markets. His work has resulted in numerous international publications, presentations, and awards (including the AdC Competition Policy Award 2019 and the Concurrences PhD Award 2022). In addition, Friso edits the CoRe Blog and hosts the Monopoly Attack podcast.

>> Friso’s CoRe Blog posts >>

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

07. Nov 2024
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
Case C-264/23 Booking.com – Ancillary restraints and market definition in the platform economy - mfn

Case C-264/23 Booking.com – Ancillary restraints and market definition in the platform economy

The recent judgment of the CJEU in Booking.com represents yet another development in the long series of cases concerning price parity clauses in the platform economy. In Booking.com’s case, the judgment represents the end of the line for its parity clauses. In its greater context of applying EU competition law in the digital economy, the judgment offers new insights into […]
18. Mrz 2024
von Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, apple app store, the digital markets act

The Apple App Store – A New Kind of Hallmark Case

After almost three years since the Commission sent Apple its statement of objections, which was significantly trimmed down, the Commission reached a finding of abuse for which it imposed a whopping fine of 1.8 billion euros. Alongside this case, Apple was also involved in an almost identical case running parallel in the Netherlands, with similar findings. Meanwhile, during these procedures, […]
16. Nov 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
platforms, dma, gatekeepers, digital markets act, apple, google, microsoft, smasung

Rebutting the gatekeeper status – what does it take?

The deadline for appeals on the gatekeeper designation under the DMA is nearing its end.  Since the DMA imposes gatekeepers with demanding obligations, it is only natural that the potential subjects of this regulation will attempt to contest this status. What remains, however, to be clarified is what prospective gatekeepers can put forward as evidence to avoid being designated as […]
07. Nov 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
app store, apple, abuse of dominance, platforms, ACM, art. 102 TFEU.

The ACM vs. Apple AppStore – A Second Chance To Get It Right

The Dutch case concerning the Apple App Store appears to make a (welcome) comeback. The case that started in 2019 came to a rather disappointing end in the summer of 2022 when the Dutch competition authority issued a public statement that gave the impression that it was satisfied with Apple’s adjustments to the App Store front in the Netherlands. This […]
26. Okt 2023
von Daniel Mandrescu
airport travel

Booking / eTraveli: assessing envelopment strategies and mixing up market power thresholds

About a month ago the European Commission announced that it was prohibiting the acquisition of eTraveli by Booking Holdings (Booking.com). The prohibition, which is a rare occurrence in itself, did not attract much attention beyond comments on the ‘ecosystem’ theory of harm which it may have introduced. But this case offers more than that. First, it shows that current practice […]
12. Sep 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
Microsoft teams antitrust claim, abuse of dominance, European commission

Microsoft III – Paving The Way To A Tying Trilogy?

This summer the European commission (finally) announced it will start a formal investigation against Microsoft following Slack’s complaint concerning the (abusive) tying or bundling or Teams to the Microsoft and Office 365 suites. Not long after, Microsoft came out with an official statement concerning the changes in its pricing and distribution strategy  of Teams it will introduce in order to […]
31. Aug 2023
von Parsa Tonkaboni
The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight? - 0122 Blog post

The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight?

Introduction On 13 July 2023, the European Court of Justice (‘ECJ’) delivered its highly anticipated ruling in CK Telecoms UK Investments v European Commission (‘CK Telecoms’). The Grand Chamber judgment is significant at the most fundamental level. It clarifies some of the core legal concepts and principles at the very heart of EU merger control. The five crucial issues the […]
18. Jan 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, refusal to supply, Lithuanian railways, bronner, essential facility, art. 102 TFEU

Case C-42/21P Lithuanian Railways – another clarification on the Bronner case law and the non-exhaustive character of art. 102 TFEU

The recent case of Lithuanian Railways provides yet another clarification on the scope of application of the Bronner case law. The Judgement of the CJEU reconfirms exceptional character of the Bronner case law and the type of situations it is intended to apply to. By doing so the CJEU potentially helps prevent future disputes of a similar  nature in the […]
03. Jan 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
facebook, competition law, abuse of dominance, art. 102 TFEU, multisided platforms, dominant position, tying and bundling, unfair trading conditions, competition economics, european commission,

On-platform Tying or Another Case of Leveraging- A Discussion on Facebook Marketplace

Just before 2022 ended the Commission sent a statement of objections to Meta regarding the potential abusive behaviour of Facebook. According to the statement of objections, Facebook may be engaging in (i) abusive tying practices with regard to Facebook Marketplace as users (i.e. consumers) that log into Facebook and are automatically also offered access to the Facebook Marketplace, without the […]
07. Dez 2022
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
market definition notice, relevant market, market power, market analysis, notice update, digital platforms, multisided markets, multisided platforms, online platforms, SSNIP test, SSNDQ test, Google android, Google shopping, merger control, abuse of dominance

The draft notice on market definition and multisided (digital) platforms – avoiding rather than resolving some of the main challenges

Approximately a month ago the Commission published its draft notice on the definition of the relevant market. The new notice is supposed to replace the old one that dates back to 1997 and thereby bring the entire process up to date with today’s new challenges, particularly in the context of digital markets. A first read of this long awaited document […]

Abonnieren Sie unseren Newsletter für aktuelle Informationen zu Entwicklungen, Konferenzen, Seminaren und Veröffentlichungen in Ihrem Interessenbereich.

Newsletter: Jetzt abonnieren