The draft notice on market definition and multisided (digital) platforms – avoiding rather than resolving some of the main challenges

market definition notice, relevant market, market power, market analysis, notice update, digital platforms, multisided markets, multisided platforms, online platforms, SSNIP test, SSNDQ test, Google android, Google shopping, merger control, abuse of dominance

Approximately a month ago the Commission published its draft notice on the definition of the relevant market. The new notice is supposed to replace the old one that dates back to 1997 and thereby bring the entire process up to date with today’s new challenges, particularly in the context of digital markets. A first read of this long awaited document leaves quite some room for improvement following the consultation round. While the draft touches upon some areas which require updating such as multisided (digital) platforms, it does not truly go beyond what has already been known for a while. This post offers some initial commentary on the new section of the market definition notice concerning multisided (digital) platforms.

The approach to the market definition – how many markets need to defined in each case?

The section on multisided (digital) platforms in the draft notice on market definition addresses the main difficulty with the definition of the relevant market, namely how many markets need or can be defined in each case. For quite a while now both academia and practice have shown that, to a large extent, this issue boils down to making a choice between defining separate markets for each of the respective platform customer groups or defining one relevant market encompassing all (or multiple) platform customer groups (see here for an extensive discussion on this choice). In previous instances it was suggested that making the choice between these two options depends on the type of multisided platform in a given case. In this regard differences we drawn between transaction and non-transaction platforms as well as matching and audience providing platforms. The first of these typologies even made its way into practice in the case of Ohio v. Amex. Nevertheless, both approaches, while valuable, have the disadvantage of being challenged by the reality of multisided digital platforms which often entail hybrid forms of platforms that cannot be easily categorized based on these categories alone (for an explanation see here). This may explain to some extent the approach of the Commission to this matter so far, which was to basically test substitutability on each side of the platform and then evaluate the number and scope of the relevant market(s) as an ex-post act rather than having a set approach to be used from the get go.

Against this background the draft of the notice on market definition does not add much beyond what is said above. The notice acknowledges the above mentioned approaches and indicates that either are possible routes to be taken in practice. Unfortunately there is not much there that would indicate when the market definition would call for one or rather multiple relevant markets – which is exactly where guidance is needed! In this respect the Bundeskartellamt provided much more guidance in its working paper. To make things a bit more confusing, it is not clear whether the practice of the Commission itself in its investigation against Apple (concerning the App Store) is fully aligned with what is indicated in the notice. In this investigation the Commission is attempting to establish a position of dominance (and abuse) with respect to online music streaming apps (such as Spotify). In this regard the market definition would not cover a platform customer group (app developers as such) but rather a sub-set or sub-segment of such a group. Such an approach is not foreseen by the draft notice and would entail significant consequences for platforms that serve large heterogenous customer groups which can then be sliced and diced in various ways for the purpose of the market definition. This similar approach has also been seen recently in the Netherlands in the case of the Dutch competition authority (ACM) against Apple, where the market definition and abuse focused on dating app providers (see earlier post). Regardless of whether one agrees with such approaches, the fact that they are used in practice should be reason enough to include them in the notice at least as an option.

The SSNIP test and its conversion to zero priced products and services

In addition to the approach to the market definition the draft notice touches upon a second key difficulty involving multisided (digital) platforms, namely the application on the SSNIP test. This difficulty has in essence two dimensions. The first once is concerned with how to apply the SSNIP test in multisided markets in light of the network effects at play. In other words, there is no consensus on whether the SSNIP test should be applied to the platform as a whole or rather to each side of the platform separately. If the latter option is chosen one must also choose whether the application should be simultaneous or sequential. On this matter the draft notice is silent – meaning that in practice this exercise will likely be tested in various forms in order to see whether some of the outcomes of application are also supported by other types of evidence in each case.

The second aspect concerns the application of the SSNIP text in zero priced market conditions which typically arise in the context of multisided digital platforms. When this challenge was first addressed, academic research suggested that the solution could be found in the conversion of the SSNIP into a SSNDQ – a quality centered test that theorizes a decrease in quality instead of an increase in price. From an economic perspective both options would be rather similar as getting less quality for the same price is equal to paying more for the same quality. This approach is also logical from a commercial / practical perspective since companies that do not or cannot compete of price will do so based on quality.

In practice this aspect of the challenge was first seen (explicitly) in the case of Google Shopping where the Commission refused to apply the SSNIP test in the absence of positive prices (para. 242-245). Later on the Commission choose to opt for the SSNDQ conversion which was applied Google Android (e.g. para. 267) and in the Google/Fitbit acquisition review (e.g. para 124). Although the shift to this conversion is in principle welcome as it allows practice to evolve and adapt to new realities, it is not clear however how the SSNDQ was operationalized in practice by the Commission. Specifically, it is not clear what procedure(s) the Commission followed to select the qualities that were tested for this purpose nor the degree of quality degradation that was applied. This is quite a significant shortcoming as it limits the predictability of the outcome for the undertakings concerned. Accordingly, as argued before, an adequate implementation of this conversion would require also providing some kind of corresponding procedural framework that covers such matters. Unfortunately, the draft notice does not touch on this matter beyond pointing out that the SSNDQ conversion constitutes a possible tool for the Commission to use when dealing with the market definition of zero priced good or services. The procedural considerations of this conversion are not mentioned. Ideally, this is something that could be addressed when the final version of the notice is drafted. However, the recent judgment of the General Court in the case of Android where the GC seems to give the Commission significant leeway in this respect thereby potentially reducing the incentive of the Commission to provide more specific guidance on this matter (paras. 174-181).

Conclusion

The draft notice on the market definition is a welcome initiative that will hopefully help make the market definition process suitable for the digital age and by doing so preserve its key role in the context of EU competition law. The additions on the specific matter of multisided (digital) platforms constitute in this respect a milestone in the formal acknowledgment of the challenges posed by such actors. Nevertheless, the offered guidance does -not suffice in order to provide undertakings, national competition authorities as well as courts with a degree of clarity they all have been waiting for. Time will tell whether more guidance is offered once the final version is draft. However that of course also depends on the submissions/ comments sent in during the consultation round. Accordingly, if the above critique resonates with you, it may be worth while submitting a comment in this round!

Tags

Über

Daniel Mandrescu

Blog editor Assistant Professor EU competition law, Europa Institute, Leiden University >> Daniel's CoRe blog posts >>

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

07. Nov 2024
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
Case C-264/23 Booking.com – Ancillary restraints and market definition in the platform economy - mfn

Case C-264/23 Booking.com – Ancillary restraints and market definition in the platform economy

The recent judgment of the CJEU in Booking.com represents yet another development in the long series of cases concerning price parity clauses in the platform economy. In Booking.com’s case, the judgment represents the end of the line for its parity clauses. In its greater context of applying EU competition law in the digital economy, the judgment offers new insights into […]
18. Mrz 2024
von Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, apple app store, the digital markets act

The Apple App Store – A New Kind of Hallmark Case

After almost three years since the Commission sent Apple its statement of objections, which was significantly trimmed down, the Commission reached a finding of abuse for which it imposed a whopping fine of 1.8 billion euros. Alongside this case, Apple was also involved in an almost identical case running parallel in the Netherlands, with similar findings. Meanwhile, during these procedures, […]
16. Nov 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
platforms, dma, gatekeepers, digital markets act, apple, google, microsoft, smasung

Rebutting the gatekeeper status – what does it take?

The deadline for appeals on the gatekeeper designation under the DMA is nearing its end.  Since the DMA imposes gatekeepers with demanding obligations, it is only natural that the potential subjects of this regulation will attempt to contest this status. What remains, however, to be clarified is what prospective gatekeepers can put forward as evidence to avoid being designated as […]
07. Nov 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
app store, apple, abuse of dominance, platforms, ACM, art. 102 TFEU.

The ACM vs. Apple AppStore – A Second Chance To Get It Right

The Dutch case concerning the Apple App Store appears to make a (welcome) comeback. The case that started in 2019 came to a rather disappointing end in the summer of 2022 when the Dutch competition authority issued a public statement that gave the impression that it was satisfied with Apple’s adjustments to the App Store front in the Netherlands. This […]
26. Okt 2023
von Daniel Mandrescu
airport travel

Booking / eTraveli: assessing envelopment strategies and mixing up market power thresholds

About a month ago the European Commission announced that it was prohibiting the acquisition of eTraveli by Booking Holdings (Booking.com). The prohibition, which is a rare occurrence in itself, did not attract much attention beyond comments on the ‘ecosystem’ theory of harm which it may have introduced. But this case offers more than that. First, it shows that current practice […]
12. Sep 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
Microsoft teams antitrust claim, abuse of dominance, European commission

Microsoft III – Paving The Way To A Tying Trilogy?

This summer the European commission (finally) announced it will start a formal investigation against Microsoft following Slack’s complaint concerning the (abusive) tying or bundling or Teams to the Microsoft and Office 365 suites. Not long after, Microsoft came out with an official statement concerning the changes in its pricing and distribution strategy  of Teams it will introduce in order to […]
31. Aug 2023
von Parsa Tonkaboni
The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight? - 0122 Blog post

The ECJ Judgment in CK Telecoms – Setting the Record Straight?

Introduction On 13 July 2023, the European Court of Justice (‘ECJ’) delivered its highly anticipated ruling in CK Telecoms UK Investments v European Commission (‘CK Telecoms’). The Grand Chamber judgment is significant at the most fundamental level. It clarifies some of the core legal concepts and principles at the very heart of EU merger control. The five crucial issues the […]
18. Jan 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
competition law, abuse of dominance, refusal to supply, Lithuanian railways, bronner, essential facility, art. 102 TFEU

Case C-42/21P Lithuanian Railways – another clarification on the Bronner case law and the non-exhaustive character of art. 102 TFEU

The recent case of Lithuanian Railways provides yet another clarification on the scope of application of the Bronner case law. The Judgement of the CJEU reconfirms exceptional character of the Bronner case law and the type of situations it is intended to apply to. By doing so the CJEU potentially helps prevent future disputes of a similar  nature in the […]
03. Jan 2023
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
facebook, competition law, abuse of dominance, art. 102 TFEU, multisided platforms, dominant position, tying and bundling, unfair trading conditions, competition economics, european commission,

On-platform Tying or Another Case of Leveraging- A Discussion on Facebook Marketplace

Just before 2022 ended the Commission sent a statement of objections to Meta regarding the potential abusive behaviour of Facebook. According to the statement of objections, Facebook may be engaging in (i) abusive tying practices with regard to Facebook Marketplace as users (i.e. consumers) that log into Facebook and are automatically also offered access to the Facebook Marketplace, without the […]
27. Okt 2022
Features von Daniel Mandrescu
tv broadcasting; competition law; art. 102 TFEU; antitrust; merger control

Opinion of AG Kokott in Case-449/21 (Towercast): filling gaps in EU merger control and creating new routes for dealing with killer acquisitions through the DMA 

Earlier this month AG Kokott delivered an opinion that quickly caught the attention of the (EU) competition law community. It covered a matter which has long been left unaddressed after the introduction of EU (and national) merger control rules, namely the possibility to apply art. 102 TFEU to concentrations.  According to AG Kokott, this possibility, which has been thought to […]

Abonnieren Sie unseren Newsletter für aktuelle Informationen zu Entwicklungen, Konferenzen, Seminaren und Veröffentlichungen in Ihrem Interessenbereich.

Newsletter: Jetzt abonnieren