Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part II)

Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part II) - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 18 1

Public service obligations must be imposed through an act of entrustment that defines clearly the terms of the service and the duration of the obligation.

The “reasonable profit” in the public service compensation should reflect the risk borne by the provider.

Introduction

In 2009, the Commission received several complaints concerning State aid that Italy had granted to the various shipping companies in the former state-owned Tirrenia group. The aid was in the form of compensation for public service obligations. Those complaints triggered several Commission investigations that led to a number of different decisions most of which found that the aid was compatible with the internal market, although in some cases the aid was incompatible with the internal market and had to be recovered.

Interestingly and rather exceptionally, the Commission also found that some of the aid measures were free of State aid because they conformed with the four Altmark conditions [see Decision 2020/1412 on Tirrenia; Decision 2021/4268 on Siremar and Toremar].

In addition, in previous decisions the Commission investigated the possible existence of State aid in favour of undertakings that in the meantime had acquired some of the aided shipping companies.

In the present case, the Commission also had to examine conformity with the Altmark conditions and the presence of State aid in the sale of Laziomar to CLN, shipping operator. This was because when CLN acquired the assets of the Laziomar, at the same time it was also encumbered with the obligation to provide public services in return for adequate compensation.

Another issue that had to be taken into account by the Commission was a berthing priority enjoyed by Laziomar, that was not available to other private ferry companies.

The Commission investigation in the measures in favour of Laziomar resulted in Decision 2022/1328 which is reviewed in this article.[1]

Italy argued that the public measures that were investigated by the Commission did not contain State aid because the public service compensation conformed with the Altmark conditions. Even if it did not conform with those conditions, any aid was compliant with the requirements of the 2012 SGEI Decision [Commission Decision 2012/21]. The number of passengers carried by Laziomar did not exceed the annual threshold of 300,000 per year laid down by Article 2(1)(d) of the 2012 Decision. With respect to the berthing priority, Italy stated that all ferry companies paid berthing fees. As for the sale to CLN, Italy insisted that a market price was paid, as CLN was chosen following a competitive selection procedure.

This article is divided into two parts. Part I reviews the assessment for the existence of State aid. Part II reviews the assessment of the compatibility of the aid with the internal market.

Part II

 Compatibility of the compensation with the internal market

Since the successive prolongations of contracts that were awarded without a tender to Laziomar were found to contain State aid, the Commission had to assess its compatibility with the internal market.

The Commission assessed it on the basis of the SGEI Decision [Decision 2012/21] and the 2012 SGEI Framework. [The Commission refers to the 2011 Framework. In fact it came into force on 31 January 2012.]

Although the annual number of passengers did not exceed the threshold of 300,000 laid down in the SGEI Decision, the entrustment act assigning the public service obligation to Laziomar did not refer to the SGEI Decision as required by Article 4 of the SGEI Decision. For this reason the Commission relied on both the SGEI Decision and the SGEI Framework to make the assessment.

Genuine service of general economic interest

Because the meaning of SGEI in Article 106(2) TFEU and the first Altmark condition are the same, the Commission applied here too the same criteria it used to determine conformity with the Altmark conditions. That is, it examined whether there was demand for the services, whether the market was unable on its own to meet that demand and whether the provision of compensation was the least harmful approach to competition [i.e. whether the imposition of public service obligations without compensation would have been sufficient]. [para 288]

The Commission first recalled that Italy imposed the public service obligations “(290) mainly to (i) ensure the territorial continuity between the mainland and the islands; and to (ii) contribute to the economic development of the islands concerned, through regular and reliable maritime transport services. The Commission already concluded […] that these are indeed legitimate public interest objectives.”

After examining statistics on passenger numbers and the services offered by other ferry operators, the Commission found that there was genuine demand for the services in question and that that demand was not wholly satisfied by the market [i.e. the services offered by other ferry operators were not sufficient]. In addition, compensation was necessary because on most routes, ferry services were loss-making during the low season. [paras 291-296]

“(297) Therefore, the Commission concludes that Italy has not made a manifest error when defining the services entrusted to Laziomar as SGEI.”

Need for an entrustment act specifying the public service obligations and the methods of calculating compensation

The act of entrustment must specify the following:

  • The precise nature of the public service obligation and its duration.
  • The undertaking and territory concerned.
  • The nature of the exclusive rights.
  • The parameters for calculating, controlling and reviewing the compensation.
  • The arrangements for avoiding and repaying any overcompensation. [para 299]

The Commission confirmed that all of the above requirements were fulfilled. [paras 300-304]

Duration of the period of entrustment

Article 2(2) of Decision 2012/21 sets 10 years as the maximum period of entrustment unless amortisation needs to be carried out over a longer period. Paragraph 17 of the SGEI Framework also provides that the period of entrustment should not exceed the period required for the depreciation of the most significant assets for the SGEI.

In the case of Laziomar, the Commission concurred with Italy that the period of entrustment corresponded to the normally long life of ferry vessels. [paras 306-308]

Amount of compensation

Paragraph 21 of the SGEI Framework stipulates that the amount of the compensation must not exceed what is necessary to cover the net cost of the public service obligation, including a reasonable profit. The net cost is the gross cost minus the gross revenue from the service that is provided

The net cost must be calculated on the basis of the “net avoided cost” methodology which is the difference between the net cost with the obligation and the net cost without the obligation. In practice, this means that fixed costs are ignored whenever they have to be borne regardless of whether the service provider is burdened with a public service obligation or not.

In this case, because the compensation was granted before the entry into force of the SGEI Framework, the use of the net avoided cost methodology was not required. “(314) Instead, alternative methods for calculating the net cost necessary to discharge the public service obligations, such as the methodology based on cost allocation can be used. Under the latter methodology, the net cost would be calculated as the difference between the costs and the revenues for a designated provider of fulfilling the public service obligations, as specified and estimated in the entrustment act.” In practice, the difference between this method and the net avoided cost method is that an appropriate share of fixed costs can be allocated to the SGEI and therefore it is eligible to receive compensation.

With respect to an appropriate profit rate, “(316) the risk premium of 6,5 % would have been applied to determine the return on capital using the WACC formula. However, […], Italy has clarified that, because the amount of compensation was capped by the 2009 Law, it was decided to simplify the calculation by applying the 6,5 % as a flat rate return on capital.”

In other words, the rate of 6.5% does not include the risk-free return or the opportunity cost of capital. It follows that the rate of 6.5% is lower than the normal return which is the sum of the risk-free return and the risk premium.

“(317) In this context, on the basis of the route-by-route accounts submitted by Italy […] the Commission could verify that for 2011, 2012 and 2013 together, the public service compensation was EUR 70 650 higher than the net cost of the service (not including any return on capital)”.

At this point, the Commission decision contains the following table for the period 2011-2013:

Total revenue 9 ,55,942
– Total costs 44,121,893
– Amortisation 74,1109
= Net cost of public service – 35,007,048
+ Return on capital at 6.5% 0
= Costs eligible for compensation – 35,007,048
+ Actual compensation 35,077,698
= Over-compensation 70,650

Since the calculations above showed over-compensation, the Commission made the following statement. “(319) The Commission notes that in the case of the three-year financial exercise, the positive difference of EUR 70 650, which represents only 0,2% of the actual compensation paid to Laziomar, is captured by the 6,5% flat rate and does not result in overcompensation. Moreover, a rate of return of 0,2% (or 20 basis points), does not exceed the relevant swap rate plus a premium of 100 basis points, which, pursuant to paragraph 36 of the 2011 SGEI Framework, is regarded as reasonable in any event.”

In other words, the over-compensation could be regarded as a return on capital at a rate that fell below the safe-harbour rate of swap rate + 1% defined in the SGEI Framework and SGEI Decision [Decision 2012/21].

However, it must be said that here the Commission is mixing up its numbers. The remuneration of capital is not the same as the amount of over-compensation. The Commission derived the rate of 0.2% by dividing the overcompensation of 70,650 by the actual compensation of 35,077,698. The denominator should have been the amount of capital employed.

Then the Commission reiterated that it had “(321) already assessed under Altmark 3 that the 6,5% flat rate return on capital that Laziomar could expect from an ex ante perspective was in line with the risks it ran when operating the public services under the public service contract”.

“(323) In addition, as already explained […] in the context of assessing the new public service contract under Altmark 3, the Commission has found that in 2013 (as well as for the whole period 2011–2013) the median return on capital generated by a benchmark group of selected ferry operators offering maritime connections within Italy or between Italy and other Member States was generally similar to the 6,5% return on capital of Laziomar.”

“(324) In view of the above, the Commission considers that the 6,5% return on capital remains at a reasonable level.”

A comment is in order here. We saw earlier in part I that the Commission paid particular attention to whether Laziomar was exposed to normal market risk. This is because the return on capital must reflect the risk borne by the service provider. Although Laziomar did bear a certain risk, some market risk was mitigated by the terms of its contract. This immediately raises the question whether the rate of 6.5% return on capital of the benchmark group of ferry operators that provided services on the market was truly representative of the risks to which Laziomar was exposed. The Commission paves over this issue without much explanation. A more thorough and robust explanation would have identified the various sources of risk and their respective impact on profitability. For example, fluctuations in fuel costs could account for, say, 30% of the variation in profits [please note that the statistical definition of risk is variance from an average]. So, if Laziomar was insulated from fluctuations of the price of fuel [i.e. if the contract provided that the compensation increased by the amount of the increase in the price of fuel or, conversely, that the compensation was reduced by the amount of reduction in the price of fuel], then the allowable profit should have been reduced by 30%.

Control of over-compensation

“(325) Italy has lastly provided the necessary evidence showing that all regular checks were carried out to ensure that the amount of the compensation did not exceed the net cost of the service. In addition, the Commission recalls that the compensation is paid out in instalments (see recital 45) and that the final pay-out is made on the basis of the actual costs and revenues of the year. This ensures that the amount of compensation does not exceed the net costs of the service.”

On the basis of the above findings, the Commission concluded that the compensation was compatible with the internal market under Article 106(2) TFEU.

Tags

Über

Phedon Nicolaides

Dr. Nicolaides was educated in the United States, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. He has a PhD in Economics and a PhD in Law. He is professor at the University of Maastricht and the University of Nicosia. He has published extensively on European integration, competition policy and State aid. He is also on the editorial boards of several journals. Dr. Nicolaides has organised seminars and workshops in many different Member States, and has acted as consultant to several public authorities.

Hinterlasse eine Antwort

Zusammenhängende Posts

23. Jan 2024
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Public Service Compensation and Indexation of Costs - State Aid Uncovered photos 2

Public Service Compensation and Indexation of Costs

Introduction Member States may impose public service obligations [PSO] on undertakings and compensate them for the extra costs they incur. The public service compensation [PSC] may also include reasonable profit. Naturally, the PSC may not cover costs that are not related to the PSO or the service of general economic interest [SGEI]. So, for multi-service providers, account separation is absolutely […]
07. Mrz 2023
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Tax Advantages and Competitive Bidding - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 9

Tax Advantages and Competitive Bidding

Introduction Award of contracts or sale of state assets through competitive bidding procedures or tenders are presumed to result in a market prices and to confer no advantage to the winner in the meaning of Article 107(1) TFEU. However, on 25 January 2023, the General Court ruled, in case T-666/21, Società Navigazione Siciliana v European Commission, that certain tax advantages […]
29. Nov 2022
von Phedon Nicolaides
What Costs Must be Included in Compensation for Public Service Obligations? - State Aid Uncovered SM posts

What Costs Must be Included in Compensation for Public Service Obligations?

Introduction The two most difficult issues in imposing a public service obligation on a providers of a service of general economic interest is, first, the correct definition of the obligation and, second, the correct calculation of the amount of compensation that covers only the net extra cost of the service. The correct definition must take into account what the market […]
16. Aug 2022
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part I) - State Aid Uncovered SM posts 19

Compensation for the Net Cost of Public Service Obligations (Part I)

Public service obligations must be imposed through an act of entrustment that defines clearly the terms of the service and the duration of the obligation. The “reasonable profit” in the public service compensation should reflect the risk borne by the provider. Introduction In 2009, the Commission received several complaints concerning State aid that Italy had granted to the various shipping […]
23. Mrz 2021
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Exclusive Rights and State Aid - StateAidHub blogpost12 Poste Italiane

Exclusive Rights and State Aid

Exclusive rights may constitute State aid if they mandate payments with resources over which the state can exercise control. Compensation for the cost of public service obligations may be granted only if the obligations are clear and define a service that is different from market services. Introduction Article 106(1) TFEU requires Member States not to distort competition when they grant […]
15. Dez 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
The Law, Economics and Art of Compensation for Public Service Obligations - post sign 1893086 1920 1

The Law, Economics and Art of Compensation for Public Service Obligations

State aid in the form of compensation for public service obligations must exclude any intangible benefits from the obligation, but may include reasonable profit. The Commission guidelines for State aid in agriculture and forestry, the block exemption regulations covering agriculture, forestry, fishery and aquaculture, and the Regulation on de minimis aid for fishery and aquaculture have been prolonged to 31 […]
08. Dez 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part II) - container 1638068 1920

A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part II)

For a service to be in the general economic interest, it must be shown to fill a gap in the market or to offer what the market fails to provide adequately. [In case you have missed part I, you can access it here.] Introduction Services of general economic interest [SGEI] are important for the functioning of European societies. However, the […]
01. Dez 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part I) - container 1638068 1920

A Rare Case of Altmark-compliant SGEI (Part I)

For a service to be in the general economic interest, it must be shown to fill a gap in the market or to offer what the market fails to provide adequately. Introduction Services of general economic interest [SGEI] are important for the functioning of European societies. However, the granting of compensation to an undertaking for the provision of SGEI must […]
15. Sep 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
Non-economic Activities and Services of General Economic Interest - environmental protection 683437 1280

Non-economic Activities and Services of General Economic Interest

Non-economic tasks and economic activities which are inseparable from those non-economic tasks are together, as a bundle, non-economic in nature. Public compensation for the extra costs of services of general economic interest [SGEI] may not cross-subsidise activities that fall outside the scope of the SGEI. Update on Temporary Framework: Number of approved and published covid-19 measures, as of 11 September […]
07. Apr 2020
State Aid Uncovered von Phedon Nicolaides
EU Decisions Override National Decisions on Compensation for Public Service Obligations - StateAidHub blogpost14 Public Service Obligations 1

EU Decisions Override National Decisions on Compensation for Public Service Obligations

The principle of res judicata cannot be used to avoid recovery of incompatible State aid.   An update on State aid measures to counter the impact of COVID-19 As of 3 April 2020, the Commission has approved 29 measures submitted by 16 Member States. Article 107(3)(b) is the legal basis for 26 of those measures, while Article 107(2)(b) is the […]